how competition can improve management quality and save lives

Similar documents
The Impact of Competition on Management Quality: Evidence from Public Hospitals

CEP Discussion Paper No 983 May 2010 (Revised November 2014)

APPLIED ECONOMICS WORKSHOP. John Van Reenen London School of Economics

Management Practices in Hospitals

CEP Discussion Paper No 983 May 2010 (Revised February 2013)

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE IMPACT OF COMPETITION ON MANAGEMENT QUALITY: EVIDENCE FROM PUBLIC HOSPITALS

The Impact of Competition on Management Quality: Evidence from Public Hospitals

Free to Choose? Reform and Demand Response in the British National Health Service

ELECTION ANALYSIS. Health: Higher Spending has Improved Quality, But Productivity Must Increase

National Schedule of Reference Costs data: Community Care Services

Announcement of methodological change

Differences in employment histories between employed and unemployed job seekers

NHS CONFEDERATION RESPONSE TO THE EMERGENCY ADMISSIONS MARGINAL RATE REVIEW (JUNE 2013)

The Impact of CEOs in the Public Sector: Evidence from the English NHS

Chasing ambulance productivity

Public satisfaction with the NHS and social care in 2017

SUPPORT FOR VULNERABLE GP PRACTICES: PILOT PROGRAMME

Organisational factors that influence waiting times in emergency departments

Market Structure and Physician Relationships in the Joint Replacement Industry

NHS Trends in dissatisfaction and attitudes to funding

Hospital at home or acute hospital care: a cost minimisation analysis Coast J, Richards S H, Peters T J, Gunnell D J, Darlow M, Pounsford J

CASE STUDY The Safer Patients Initiative

ANSWERS TO QUESTIONS YOU MAY HAVE

2017 National NHS staff survey. Results from London North West Healthcare NHS Trust

Can we monitor the NHS plan?

Plan for investment of retained marginal rate payment for emergency admissions in Gloucestershire

What Job Seekers Want:

Charlotte Banks Staff Involvement Lead. Stage 1 only (no negative impacts identified) Stage 2 recommended (negative impacts identified)

Transforming Primary Care

Key facts and trends in acute care

E valuation of healthcare provision is essential in the ongoing

Utilisation Management

«Vers un système de santé national britannique centré sur le patient»

Carole Smee NHSIQ. 2 nd Dec Seven Day Services Improvement Programme

Document Details Clinical Audit Policy

The Guy s and St Thomas NHS Foundation Trust Neighbourhood Nursing Team Test and Learn project of an adapted Buurtzorg model: An early view

The new CQC approach to hospital inspection. Ann Ford Head of Hospital Inspection (North West) June 2014

Creating a Patient-Centered Payment System to Support Higher-Quality, More Affordable Health Care. Harold D. Miller

WHY OFFER SAME DAY DISCHARGE FOR NON-RECONSTRUCTIVE BREAST CANCER SURGERY?

Do quality improvements in primary care reduce secondary care costs?

WEST CORNWALL HEALTHWATCH

Plans for urgent care in west Kent:

Case study: how reliable are our healthcare systems?

Birmingham Solihull and the Black Country Area Team

MODERNISING THE NHS: The Health and Social Care Bill

Briefing April 2017 Nuffield Winter Insight Briefing 3: The ambulance service

Shetland NHS Board. Board Paper 2017/28

Vertical integration: who should join up primary and secondary care?

Our NHS, our future. This Briefing outlines the main points of the report. Introduction

Composite Results and Comparative Statistics Report

Referral to Treatment Pathways for Surgical Carpal Tunnel Syndrome Patients

Factors associated with variation in hospital use at the End of Life in England

NHS Services, Seven Days a Week

Community Performance Report

Re: Rewarding Provider Performance: Aligning Incentives in Medicare

COLLABORATIVE SERVICES SHOW POSITIVE OUTCOMES FOR END OF LIFE CARE

England. Questions and Answers. Draft Integrated Care Provider (ICP) Contract - consultation package

Efficiency in mental health services

The PCT Guide to Applying the 10 High Impact Changes

Appendix. We used matched-pair cluster-randomization to assign the. twenty-eight towns to intervention and control. Each cluster,

An Evaluation of Health Improvements for. Bowen Therapy Clients

Use of social care data for impact analysis and risk stratification

New Joints: Private providers and rising demand in the English National Health Service

2017 National NHS staff survey. Results from Salford Royal NHS Foundation Trust

2017 National NHS staff survey. Results from Nottingham University Hospitals NHS Trust

Working Paper Series

Demand and capacity models High complexity model user guidance

Practice nurses in 2009

NATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF SPECIALTY PHARMACY PATIENT SURVEY PROGRAM

Low pay in care work the importance of hours

The 18-week wait programme

Monitoring hospital mortality A response to the University of Birmingham report on HSMRs

Mental Health Community Service User Survey 2017 Management Report

2016 National NHS staff survey. Results from Wirral University Teaching Hospital NHS Foundation Trust

Are R&D subsidies effective? The effect of industry competition

Leadership on Distance: The Effects of Distance on Communication, Trust and Motivation

SUMMARY REPORT TRUST BOARD IN PUBLIC 3 May 2018 Agenda Number: 9

Measuring the Quality of Outcomes in Healthcare using HIPE data

Mental Health URGENT CARE AND ASSESSMENT Business Case. CCG Summary paper

CLINICAL STRATEGY IMPLEMENTATION - HEALTH IN YOUR HANDS

Optical Confederation response to Enablers and Barriers to Integrated Care and Implications for Monitor

The Cumbria Local Health Economy Strategic Plan

Inpatient and Community Mental Health Patient Surveys Report written by:

CHE Research Paper 151. Spatial Competition and Quality: Evidence from the English Family Doctor Market

Discussion paper on the Voluntary Sector Investment Programme

BOLTON NHS FOUNDATION TRUST. expansion and upgrade of women s and children s units was completed in 2011.

Outpatient Experience Survey 2012

September Workforce pressures in the NHS

Better Healthcare in Bucks Reconfiguring acute services

Emergency admissions to hospital: managing the demand

National Patient Experience Survey Mater Misericordiae University Hospital.

Health and Social Care Select Committee report Integrated care: organisations, partnerships and systems

Meeting of the European Parliament Interest Group on Carers

Financial mechanisms for integrating funds across health & social care

Ambulatory emergency care Reimbursement under the national tariff

Higher Education Funding Reforms. Clinical Placements

Identifying Evidence-Based Solutions for Vulnerable Older Adults Grant Competition

End of Life Care. LONDON: The Stationery Office Ordered by the House of Commons to be printed on 24 November 2008

Quick Facts VIP Survey: Trends in Federal Contracting for Small Businesses 1

Understanding NHS financial pressures

Transcription:

NHS hospitals in England are rarely closed in constituencies where the governing party has a slender majority. This means that for near random reasons, those parts of the country have more competition in healthcare which has allowed Nicholas Bloom and John Van Reenen to assess its impact on management quality and clinical performance. BLUE IS No.1 Healthcare: how competition can improve management quality and save lives Throughout the world, the share of national income absorbed by healthcare seems to rise inexorably. Technological progress, rising citizen expectations and an ageing population have all helped to propel this escalation in costs. In the United States, almost one dollar in every five is spent on health. In an era of budgetary austerity, policy-makers have been searching desperately for ways to improve the efficiency of healthcare delivery without jeopardising the quality of clinical care. Nowhere is this greater than in hospitals, which are a major component of total healthcare costs. To an economist, a natural method of improving efficiency is through competition. If patients had more effective, well-informed choice between hospitals, then wouldn t managers work harder to improve services to attract them? But, it is traditionally argued, healthcare is different because of multiple market failures. For example, patients typically have poor information about hospital quality and are also unwilling to travel far for healthcare; local doctors are sometimes subject to conflicting incentives; and healthcare is heavily regulated with services often delivered directly by the public sector. Nevertheless, there has recently been a wave of reform in the public services of many countries to create quasi-markets and inject greater degrees of patient choice. In work with Carol Propper and Healthcare competition can be introduced by improving information, giving patients more choice and having money follow patients 7

GO! RED 8

Stephan Seiler, we evaluate whether competition improves hospital quality, in particular by stimulating greater managerial effort (Bloom et al, 2015). We do this in the context of the acute care hospitals in the NHS. In the 2000s under the Labour government, resources followed patients and publicly run NHS hospitals had to attract patients to obtain such resources. But since the prices for hospital services were centrally set, the only way hospitals could attract extra patients was by improving quality. Helped by their GPs, patients were given the choice of at least five hospitals and much better information. Since people dislike travelling far from where they live, hospital competition has a strong geographical element. If competition works, then it should do so more in those areas of the country where there are many hospitals to choose from rather than a single monopoly provider. There are two major challenges in addressing the question of whether having more hospital competition really improves management. First, how to design an experiment that randomly generates more hospitals in some parts of the country than others; and second, how to measure management quality. Using politics as an experiment The institutional features of the NHS provide a natural experiment for hospital market competition. Entry and exit of hospitals is centrally controlled by the Department of Health and over the last 40 years and in particular since the mid-1990s there has been an attempt to reduce the number of hospitals and consolidate services in a smaller number of larger hospitals. Changes in population and demographics are a key consideration in making decisions about how to reconfigure these services. But politics also matters. Closing down a hospital is highly controversial as local people will usually fight hard to keep it open. A vivid example of this was in the 2001 General Election when a government minister was overthrown by a politically independent physician, Dr Richard Taylor, who campaigned on the single issue of saving the local Kidderminster Hospital, which the government planned to scale down. Policy reforms to improve patient choice could help deal with the healthcare funding crisis We first show what might seem obvious: people blame the central government in power for closing down a hospital and punish them at the ballot box. Hence, it is no surprise that hospitals are rarely closed in constituencies where there is likely to be a close electoral race. For example, the Times reported on 15 September 2006 that A secret meeting has been held by ministers and Labour Party officials to work out ways of closing hospitals without jeopardising key marginal seats. Figure 1 shows the number of hospitals in 2005 per head of the population in English constituencies in relation to their political marginality in the 1997 election. There is a surprisingly large number of hospitals in the areas where Labour won or lost with a voting margin of 5% or less. And this relationship holds even after a large number of controls for the area is included, such as income, demographics and population density (the first bar of Figure 2 shows that areas that were marginal had over a standard deviation more hospitals than those that were not marginal). This enables us to use the political marginality of an area as something that for random reasons means that some areas will have more hospitals and therefore more intense competition than others. It is a natural experiment that gives an additional dose of competition to some areas, which we can compare with others with less competition. Measuring the quality of hospital management The second question is how to measure hospital management quality. We build on a method for quantifying core aspects of management quality that we first used in 2004 for 732 manufacturing firms in four countries (Bloom and Van Reenen, 2007). Since then, the World Management Survey has been expanded to over 20,000 organisations in multiple sectors in 35 countries. For hospitals, the core of our dataset is made up of 18 questions, which can be grouped into the following sub-categories: operations and monitoring (six questions); targets (five questions); and incentives (seven questions). For each of the questions, the interviewer reports a score between 1 and 5, a higher score indicating better performance. To try to obtain unbiased responses, we use a double blind survey methodology. The first part is that the interview is conducted by telephone without telling the respondents in advance that they are being scored. This enables scoring to be based on the interviewer s evaluation of the hospital s actual practices, rather than their aspirations, the respondent s perceptions or the interviewer s impressions. To run this blind scoring, we use open questions ( can you tell me how you promote your employees? ) rather than closed questions ( do you promote your employees based on tenure yes or no? ). Furthermore, these questions target actual practices and examples, with the discussion continuing until the interviewer can make an accurate assessment of the hospital s typical practices based on these examples. For each practice, the first question is broad with detailed follow-up questions to fine-tune the scoring. For example, with question (1) Layout of patient flow, the initial question Can you briefly describe the patient journey or flow for a typical episode? is followed up by questions like How closely located are wards, theatres and diagnostics centres? The second part of the double-blind 9

Figure 1: Labour s winning margin in 1997 and the number of hospitals per head in a political constituency in 2005 Number of hospitals per million population 6.0 5.5 5.0 4.5 4.0 3.5 3.0 Safe seats Marginal seats Safe seats -15 < x < -10-10 < x < -5-5 < x < 0 0 < x < 5 5 < x < 10 10 < x < 15 Winning margin Notes: This figure plots the mean number of hospitals per one million people within a 15km radius of the centre of a political constituency against the winning margin in 1997 of the governing party (Labour). When Labour is not the winning party, the margin is the negative of the difference between the winning party (usually Conservative) and Labour. The margin is denoted x. There are 529 political constituencies in England. Figure 2: Areas of high competition have more hospitals, better management and lower in-hospital death rates Differences between high and low marginality constituencies 1.2 0.9 0.6 0.3 0.0-0.3-0.6 Number of hospitals Management quality Heart attack mortality Notes: This figure plots the differences between high and low marginality constituencies (split at the median of marginality after controlling for the baseline regression covariates). All three measures control for many other factors (they are residuals from a regression on these covariates) to strip out the effects of demographics, teaching hospitals, being located in London, etc. The difference between low and high marginality is statistically significant at 1% for the number of hospitals and management quality; and at the 10% level for heart attack mortality rates. scoring methodology is that the interviewers are not told anything about the hospital s performance in advance of the interview. This is collected postinterview from a wide range of other sources. We interview respondents for an average of just under an hour and approach up to four individuals in every hospital a manager and a physician from both the cardiology and orthopaedic services. We obtained 161 interviews in 100 acute hospitals and the response probability was uncorrelated with performance and other hospital characteristics. Our management quality index built from averaging these 18 questions was strongly correlated with a range of measures of clinical performance (such as surgical survival rates), productivity and staff satisfaction. These relationships are not necessarily causal, but suggest that the questions have useful informational content. Competition improves management and clinical quality Overall, we find that hospitals that faced more competition had significantly higher management scores and better clinical and financial performance. Using only the random variation in the degree of competition generated by political marginality actually made this relationship between competition and quality stronger. This could be because it is harder to attract good managers to work in areas that are poor and ageing exactly those areas where health demand and the number of hospitals per head are relatively large. The magnitude of the competition effect is sizeable. For example, we estimate that adding a rival hospital increases management quality by 0.4 standard deviations and increases survival rates from emergency heart attacks by 8.8%. An illustration of this is in Figure 2: comparing areas that are marginal with those that are not, we find that politically marginal areas had higher management quality (middle bar) and lower death rates (right bar). We confirm the robustness of our empirical strategy to hidden policies that could be used in marginal constituencies to improve hospital management and to changes in capacity that may follow from hospital closure. One concern is that 10

Nicholas Bloom of Stanford University is a research associate in CEP s growth programme. John Van Reenen is director of CEP. GOOD GREEN marginality might have direct effects on hospitals through other routes than competition. We show that this is not the case there is a national funding formula and we confirm that marginality has no effect on financial resources per hospital. Because hospital markets are overlapping, we can even implement a tough test that puts in marginality around a hospital and just uses variation in marginality around its rival hospitals to identify the competition effects. We confirm the absence of such hidden policies associated with political marginality. Policy conclusions Competition can be introduced into public systems by improving information, giving patients and their GPs choice and having money follow the patients. This is a cheaper way of inducing competition than simply building more hospitals, which is expensive. At the moment, decisions over entry and exit of hospitals in public systems usually ignore the effects of competition. Our work suggests that market structure should not be ignored. The quasi-market in the NHS remains controversial. When our findings on the benefits of competition were first discussed in the media, one of our team members received death threats and had to have security protection when leaving the LSE buildings. The main objection is that the reforms in the 2000s were thought to be privatising the NHS. This is wrong: NHS hospitals are publicly owned hospitals and free at the point of use. Importantly, hospitals are not allowed to compete on price, which is set as a national tariff per treatment type. That leaves quality as the dimension that is open to attract patients. Allowing competition on quality but not price is a safeguard built on experience from the early 1990s internal market (Propper et al, 2008), when price competition was briefly allowed and led to cuts in costs but also to reductions in quality (which is harder to observe). Our study also suggests an important role for management. Healthcare is like many other sectors where there is significant scope for improved managerial quality to raise performance. Competition is one way but there are others improved skills (especially choosing chief executives with some clinical experience) and providing better information are two leading possibilities. There is a large role for improved managerial quality to raise hospitals performance Further reading Nicholas Bloom, Carol Propper, Stephan Seiler and John Van Reenen (2015) The Impact of Competition on Management Quality: Evidence from Public Hospitals, Review of Economic Studies 82: 457-89; earlier version available as CEP Discussion Paper No. 983 (http://cep.lse.ac.uk/pubs/ download/dp0983.pdf). Nicholas Bloom and John Van Reenen (2007) Measuring and Explaining Management Practices across Firms and Nations, Quarterly Journal of Economics 122(4): 1351-1408; earlier version available as CEP Discussion Paper No. 716 (http://cep.lse.ac.uk/ pubs/download/dp0716.pdf). Carol Propper, Simon Burgess and Denise Gossage (2008) Competition and Quality: Evidence from the NHS Internal Market 1991-99, Economic Journal 118: 138-70. 11