Misthinking globalisation

Similar documents
the great unbundling(s)

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Global value chains and globalisation. International sourcing

Global Supply Chains and Outsourcing

International Trade: Economics and Policy. LECTURE 16: Foreign outsourcing

Globalisation: the great unbundling(s)

Offshoring: General equilibrium effect on wages, production and trade. Richard Baldwin and. Frédéric Robert-Nicoud 20/01/2007. A new paradigm?

Nearshoring is a valuable part of a company's logistics strategy

5. Trends in international sourcing. Authors René Bongard Bastiaan Rooijakkers Fintan van Berkel

RODNEY S RAVING. Regional winners and losers from the evolving economy EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Chapter 9: Labor Section 1

Global Value Chains: Impacts and Implications. Aaron Sydor Office of the Chief Economist Foreign Affairs and International Trade Canada

Institutional theory and digital labour in developing countries

Address by Minister for Jobs Enterprise and Innovation, Richard Bruton TD Launch of the Grand Coalition for Digital Jobs Brussels 4th March, 2013

The Future of Non-food Sourcing. The Sourcing Landscape

US SERVICES TRADE AND OFF-SHORING

energy industry chain) CE3 is housed at the

PACIFIC ISLANDS FORUM SECRETARIAT

Business Globalization

ICC policy recommendations on global IT sourcing Prepared by the Commission on E-Business, IT and Telecoms

Ireland Future R&D Investment in a Small Open Economy Opportunities and Threats. Third KEI Workshop Helsinki

International Sourcing measurement issues. Peter Bøegh Nielsen Statistics Denmark

OUTSOURCING IN THE UNITED STATES MARKET

Contents: Page 1-2: Interviews with retained executive search consultants. Page 3-4: The outlook for the financial services industry.

Impact of Outsourcing Jobs - Economies of Wealthy and Poor Nations

Grand Overview: Shared Services & BPO

14.54 International Trade Lecture 25: Offshoring Do Old Rules Still Apply?

Industrial Strategy Green Paper. Consultation Response Manufacturing Northern Ireland

Keynote paper given by Gary Rolfe at the Portuguese Nurses Association Conference, Lisbon, Portugal, November 2010

Can Africa, India and the Middle East (AIM) transform the world s economic outlook?

Inclusive Digital Entrepreneurship Platform for Africa

Innovation Union Flagship Initiative

Chapter 11: The Economy and Work LECTURE SLIDES

Innovation, Entrepreneurship and Rural Development: Some Key Themes

Trading Tasks: Globalization in the Information Age

Business Environment and Knowledge for Private Sector Growth: Setting the Stage

Chapter 29. Introduction. Learning Objectives. The Labor Market: Demand, Supply, and Outsourcing

The Future of the Nonprofit Sector in China Speech at the American Chamber of Commerce Hong Kong, January 2010 By James Abruzzo

HONG KONG POSTS SECOND QUARTERLY RISE IN JOB ADVERTISEMENTS, SINGAPORE DOWN SLIGHTLY QUARTER ON QUARTER

Offshoring offshor. Richard B. Freeman, Harvard, NBER, National Academy of Engineering The Offshoring of Engineering, Oct 24-25,2006

REGIONS BRIDGING THE DIVIDE: THE ROLE OF TRADABLE SECTORS AND WELL FUNCTIONING CITIES

Unemployment. Rongsheng Tang. August, Washington U. in St. Louis. Rongsheng Tang (Washington U. in St. Louis) Unemployment August, / 44

United Nations Millennium Development Goals - WGO s Green Office Awards Labelling Scheme (GOALS) Fact Sheet

LONDON AND THE UK A GREAT OPPORTUNITY FOR CHINESE COMPANIES AND INVESTORS

Direct Hire Agency Benchmarking Report

Determinants of Competitiveness and Factors affecting Productivity in Services

New Brunswick Information & Communications Technology Sector Strategy

Factors and policies affecting services innovation: some findings from OECD work

The BountyJobs Headhunter Index:

COLORADO FIRST AND EXISTING INDUSTRY CUSTOMIZED TRAINING PROGRAM FISCAL YEAR 2014 REPORT TO THE JOINT BUDGET COMMITTEE

GEOGRAPHY GCSE Revision EDEXCEL B

International Trade Multinational Firms: an Introduction

Reshoring in Manufacturing and Services

Reshoring Text for IEDC s Economic Development Marketing and Attraction training manual

FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN CATALONIA AND BARCELONA

CHRISTOPHER A. PISSARIDES: SCIENTIST AND PUBLIC CITIZEN. Costas Azariadis, Washington University in St. Louis

Chicago Scholarship Online Abstract and Keywords. U.S. Engineering in the Global Economy Richard B. Freeman and Hal Salzman

Innovative and Vital Business City

Can shifting sands be a solid foundation for growth?

The Goal: most competitive and dynamic knowledge-based economy in the world

Putting Finland in the context

Macro Economy Research Conference CHINA S TRANSITION AND THE GLOBAL ECONOMY Hotel Okura Tokyo, November 13, 2012 DRC

Econ 340. Lecture 22 Outsourcing and Offshoring

World Energy Transition

Chapter The Importance of ICT in Development The Global IT Sector

Chapter One. Globalization. Globalization of Markets. Globalization of Markets. What is Globalization? Opening Case: The Globalization of Health Care

Manufacturing, exports and jobs for California and America Policies for economic growth and competitiveness

ENTREPRENEURSHIP. Training Course on Entrepreneurship Statistics September 2017 TURKISH STATISTICAL INSTITUTE ASTANA, KAZAKHSTAN

How to increase national absorptive capacity for green technology

Globalization and Growth

PRIORITY 1: Access to the best talent and skills

Annual Job Growth Projected to Approach 60,000 by 2017

An Introduction to Medical Tourism

Government policies to foster entrepreneurship

The primary care pressure cooker

Some of the key elements in our R&D program are set out as follows:

EC International Trade Multinational Firms: an Introduction

IT OUTSOURCING AND SHARED SERVICES TRENDS

Cluster Best Practices: Lessons from the Field

Integra. International Corporate Capabilities th Street NW, Suite 555W, Washington, DC, Tel (202)

Total Quality Management (TQM)

Health impact assessment, health systems, health & wealth

May 25, Prosperity and Growth Strategy for Northern Ontario

- the EIT and KICs contribution -

International Business 7e

Ambition Nation Report

Paper 2. Changing Economic World 2

The Globalization of the Executive Search Industry in Europe

CSR PRACTICE TOWARDS RESPONSIBLE BUSINESS

APEC Best Practices Guidelines on Industrial Clustering for Small and Medium Enterprises

Does access to information technology make people happier? Insights from well-being surveys from around the world*

Setting the Scene for a Future Singapore. KPMG Pre-Budget 2016 Report

The EU ICT Sector and its R&D Performance. Digital Economy and Society Index Report 2018 The EU ICT sector and its R&D performance

Small Business and the Road to Economic Recovery

Portland Economic Opportunities Analysis October 2012

Fitsum Andargue, PMP. Discussion on Outsourcing Opportunities for Ethiopia. Fitsum Andargue

Industrialization 4.0: Challenges to Higher Education Institutions. Nopraenue S. Dhirathiti

Q Manpower. Employment Outlook Survey Global. A Manpower Research Report

Luc Gregoire Chief Financial Officer. Internet & Technology Services Conference. February,

Digital Disruption: Embracing an Integrated Digital Ecosystem

The Emerging New Global Geography of Innovation

Transcription:

Keynote Speech 1 Misthinking globalisation Richard Baldwin Graduate Institute, Geneva and University of Oxford. 1. INTRODUCTION Globalisation is typically viewed as driven by the gradual lowering of natural and man-made trade costs. This is a serious mistake. Globalisation should be viewed as two processes, not one. Globalisation leaped forward in the late 19 th century when steam power slashed the costs of moving goods internationally. Globalisation made a second leap in the late 20 th century when ICT radically lower the cost of moving ideas internationally. The two leaps had dramatically different effects as can be seen from Figure 1. Figure 1: Globalisation: One paradigm or two? 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% G7 world GDP share 1820, 22% 1988, 67% 2010, 50% 1820 1839 1858 1877 1896 1915 1934 1953 1972 1991 2010 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% G7 world trade share 1950, 43% 1991, 52% 2011, 32% 2008 2002 1996 1990 1984 1978 1972 1966 1960 1954 1948

The first leap what might be called old-paradigm globalisation fostered economic agglomeration in large industrialised nations. The G7 nations saw their share of world GDP soar from a fifth in 1820 to two-thirds in 1988. G7 world trade shares also rose steadily. The second leap what might be called new-paradigm globalisation reversed this. In just two decades the G7 s shares of world GDP and trade plummeted to 50% and 32% respectively. This distinction, which I first posited in Baldwin (2006), requires some background. 2. THE 1 ST UNBUNDLING Since the dawn of human civilisation, high costs of moving goods, ideas and people forced the geographic bundling of production and consumption; every village made almost everything it consumed. Globalisation meant lowering the costs of moving goods across borders. This made it feasible to geographical unbundling production and consumption of goods. Once it was feasible, the vast international differences in efficiency made it profitable. Trade boomed. 2.1. Globalisation policy: 1 st unbundling and old-paradigm thinking The intellectual framework we use today when thinking about globalisation (mainly trade theory) was formulated during this phase. There were two key economic insights from this old-paradigm thinking. A nation s economy was connected to the world mainly via goods markets. Further globalisation was viewed as an intensification of goods markets competition. This impacted different sectors differently. A nation s best sectors what could be called sunrise sectors gained as freer competition allowed them to win markets abroad. The nation s worst sectors sunset sectors lost. Sunrise and sunset sectors were associated with distinct skill groups. For rich nations, sunrise sectors tended to hire skilled workers and employ high-

technology much more than the sunset sectors. Globalisation s winners were associated with skilled workers and high technology, the losers with unskilled workers and lowtech. Wise government realised that globalisation created winners and losers but that the winners won more than the losers lost, so they adopted policies to share the gains and pains. Education, technology and industrial policies were designed to help sunrise sectors rise faster. Social policy, subsidies, and employment laws were crafted to lessen the pain in sunset sectors and dis-favoured skill groups. The entire European social market economy model rests on this notion of fostering open markets while sharing the gains and pains. Importantly, the pace of the 1 st unbundling could be controlled in the post-war period by lowering tariffs gradually. This gave time for moving resources out of sunset sectors and into sunrise sectors. Old-paradigm thinking taught governments to think of globalisation as a slow, predictable process whose economic effects hit sectors and skill group. This changed when the ICT revolution sparked the 2 nd unbundling just as steam power sparked the 1 st. 3. THE 2 ND UNBUNDLING During the 1 st unbundling production dispersed internationally but, paradoxically, it clustered nationally (factories and industrial districts). The paradox is resolved with three points: i) cheap transport favoured large-scale production, ii) such production tends to be very complex, and iii) close proximity lowers the cost of coordinating complexity. In other words, relaxing the transportation constraint brought to the fore another constraint on location the coordination constraint. Coordinating the process demands continuous flows of goods, ideas and people. Stages bundled into factories to save on coordination costs. From the mid-1980s, the ICT revolution made it economical to separate manufacturing stages. Once it was feasible, vast international wage differences made it profitable and some stages were offshored.

3.1. How 2 nd unbundling globalisation is different The 2 nd unbundling, or new-paradigm globalisation, impacts the economy with a finer degree of resolution. More intense competition is felt at the level of stages, or even occupations rather than sectors. Globalisation s effect are felt at the stages or occupations level, not at the sectors or skill groups. The 2 nd unbundling s impact is also more sudden. Unlike tariffs, ICT cannot be easily controlled or slowed. Finally, the impact is also more unpredictable. While most traded goods were affected more or less proportionally by lower trade costs, it is difficult to predict which stages become footloose as ICT progresses. To summarise, new-paradigm globalisation more individual, more sudden and more unpredictable. 3.2. 2 nd unbundling as a technological not trade phenomenon From a more factual perspective, the radically different impact shown in the Figure 1 stems from the fact that the 2 nd unbundling is really about know-how, not trade. It is a trap to even think about the 2 nd unbundling as a trade phenomenon. The 2 nd unbundling means firms from high-technology nations recombine their firm-specific managerial, technical and marketing know-how with developing-nation labour. After all, the off-shored stages have to mesh seamlessly and evolve in tandem with the rest of the production network. The firm-level motive is to leverage the value of their firm-specific know-how by combining it with low wages in developing nations. Trade and investment are merely symptoms of this phenomenon. 3.3. 21 st century globalisation policy and new-paradigm thinking Because globalisation s impact is individual, sudden, and unpredictable, wise governments should adjust policies that were developed to deal with economic consequences of the 1 st unbundling. Since it is much harder to identify the sunrise sectors, education, technology and industrial policy should be more nuanced, and more nimble.

With new-paradigm globalisation the share of workers with lifetime jobs, or who spend a lifetime in one sector will diminish. Workers retraining will become more important; learning to learn may become as important to a worker s competitiveness as learning itself. Wise governments can reduce the pains from globalisation by getting children used to the idea that they will be engaged in life-long learning, and providing the right institutions and incentives for continuing education and skill retraining. Labour market policies should also be adapted. Europe has two basic flavours of labour market policies some nations (e.g. Denmark) protect workers, other (e.g. Spain) protect jobs. When globalisation impacted economies in a gradual, predictable manner, the distinction was important but not critical. The individuality, suddenness and unpredictability of new-paradigm globalisation make flexibility far, far more important. Firms that are locked into particular workers doing particular jobs will have an incentive to move much more of the production process abroad. Offshoring provides the ultimate labour market flexibility. Nations should shift toward protecting workers, not jobs. Industrial policy is also much harder in a landscape of work that is fragmented, footloose, and unpredictable. Even if the policy identifies an activity worthy of being promoted, how can we be sure that the promoted production stays in nation promoting it? Wise governments must work out how internationally mobile various factors are and are likely to be. Mobile and immobile factors matter; both contribute to national income. But good jobs created locally have a local multiplier effect that good jobs created abroad do not (Moretti 2010). This suggests that an important consideration for policy should be stickiness of the inputs affected by the policy. 3.4. The smile curve and cities as 21 st century factories 2 nd unbundling created winners and losers at the stage-of-production level rather than at the sector level. As it turns out, stages related to fabrication of goods have been systemic losers in rich nations and systemic winners in emerging markets. In rich nations, the winners tend to be the pre- and post-fabrication services things like design, marketing, managing complex supply chains, retail services, and after sales services.

Governments need to understand why value-added shares have shifted along value chain in rich nations, and how this has turned some formerly good jobs into bad jobs (Baldwin and Evenett 2013). The key concept is the so-called smile curve. Due to the 2 nd unbundling, some stages moved abroad; others did not. Importantly, the distribution of value added along the value chain shifted away from the offshored fabrication stages. The standard assertion is that the smile curve has gone from flat (jobs all along the chain were good ) to U-shaped, with fabrication stages especially final assembly now receiving much lower shares of value than under old-paradigm globalisation (Figure 2). Figure 2: The smile curve, good and bad stages in the value chain. Stage s share of product s value added 21 st century value chain 1970s value chain Pre-fabrication services Fabrication Post-fabrication services Stage The economics of the smile curve are simple (Baldwin 2013). Fabrication adds value in ways that are easily reproduced and easily moved. Since rich-nation firms have a wide choice of where to put offshoring production, fabrication became commoditised. The pre- and post- fabrication services, however, have not been commoditized. These services require agglomerations of talented workers interacting quickly and flexible to produce value that is difficult to copy. Mass production techniques work well for fabrication but not for pre- and post-fabrication services. In rich nations, factory jobs have become bad jobs, pre- and post-fabrication services have become good jobs.

Apple in the US and Nokia in Finland are good examples. As far as policy is concerned the key point here is cities have become richnations 21 st century factories. Wise governments should start thinking about urban policy as part of their globalisation and industrial policy. Good factory jobs for lowskilled workers are a thing of the past in rich nations. They are competing with robots at home and China abroad. The good jobs the ones that won t drift offshore suddenly and unpredictability will be in cities that agglomerate broad and deep talent pools. 4. CONCLUDING REMARKS Thinking about 21 st century globalisation with 20 th century intellectual frameworks is leading governments to make all sorts of policy mistakes. It s time for a rethink. References Baldwin, Richard (2006). "Globalisation: The great unbundling(s)." Economic Council of Finland 20 (2006): 5-47. Baldwin, Richard (2013). Global Supply Chains: From Past, to Present, to Future, Working Paper FGI-2012-1, Fung Global Institute, Hong Kong. Baldwin, Richard and Simon Evenett (2012), Value Creation and Trade in 21st Century Manufacturing: What Policies for UK Manufacturing? in Greenaway (ed.), The UK in a Global World: How can the UK focus on steps in global value chains that really add value?, BIS, CEPR, and ESRC, 14 June. Moretti, Enrico (2012). The New Geography of Jobs, Princeton University Press.