Department of Economics Working Paper

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Department of Economics Working Paper"

Transcription

1 Department of Economics Working Paper Number September 2011 Uncle Sam Wants Whom? The Draft and the Quality of Military Personnel Timothy Perri Appalachian State University Department of Economics Appalachian State University Boone, NC Phone: (828) Fax: (828)

2 Uncle Sam Wants Whom? The Draft and the Quality of Military Personnel by Timothy Perri* First version: March 2010 This version: August 08, 2011 * Department of Economics, Appalachian State University, Boone, NC, (perritj@gmail.com) JEL categories: D61, J45 Key words: conscription, volunteer military, testing

3 Abstract It has been argued the draft may enable the military to attract more able individuals than a volunteer military and thus increase welfare. We find this may be the case if a volunteer military simply takes the least able individuals. Ignoring the deadweight loss from taxation, when the military tests individuals, does not take the lowest quality applicants, and the test is costless and accurate, neither a random draft nor a draft with testing increases welfare, and both usually decrease welfare. Only if testing is relatively costly or imprecise would a random draft dominate a volunteer military with testing. With either a low quality volunteer military or imprecise testing, a volunteer military is more likely to be preferable to a draft the larger the size of the military. The opposite is the case with either costly testing or deadweight loss from taxation to support the military. Page 2 of 27

4 1. Introduction The U.S. military has become more skilled over time. The military defines high quality recruits as those who are high school graduates and who score in the top 50% on the Armed Forces Qualification Test (AFQT). 1 From 1981 to 2004, the percentage of high quality recruits went from 34 to 72 (Army), 55 to 66 (Navy), 49 to 69 (Marines), and 60 to 81 (Air Force) (Asch et al., 2005). In 2006, 91% of U.S. military recruits were high school graduates, compared to 80% for all U.S. residents ages In 2001, 18% of U.S. recruits worked in information technology related tasks, and almost 30% of these individuals were considered information technology core positions (Hosek et al., 2004). 2 For over twenty years, economists have suggested a draft might be preferable to a volunteer military when the quality of military personnel is important. Ross (1990, 1994) considered the merits of a draft when the quality of personnel is not homogeneous. 3 He found a draft might be superior to a volunteer military. More recently, Berck and Lipow (forthcoming) suggest a positive relation between civilian and military productivity may mean one of the usual costs associated with the draft---the wrong people are inducted---may disappear. There are several limitations with the previous analyses of a draft with heterogeneous labor quality. First, there are costs other than the wrong individuals being inducted that remain with a draft. Asch et al. (2005) note military personnel quality depends on a taste for the military and individual effort. Becker (1957) also considered the reduced effort to be expected with 1 The Armed Forces Qualification Test (AFQT) is based on the Armed Services Vocational Aptitude Battery (ASVAB). The ASVAB has 10 sub-tests. The AFQT is computed by adding the following: the scores on arithmetic reasoning and math knowledge, and double the scores on paragraph comprehension and word knowledge. Thus, the AFQT roughly measures verbal and quantitative skills (Hosek and Mattock, 2003). The top X% on the AFQT means these individuals scored where the top X% of enlisted personnel and officers scored during World War Two. The AFQT has changed over time so comparability between time periods is somewhat questionable (Pirie, 1980). 2 Information technology related positions include navigators and radar operators. Core IT positions include system operators and network analysts (Hosek et al., 2004). 3 Ross (1990) is an unpublished version of Ross (1994). The former has a more detailed discussion of heterogeneous labor quality. I thank Tom Ross for providing me his unpublished paper. Page 3 of 27

5 conscripts relative to volunteers. Second, if the military attempts to draft the more able, these individuals will try to appear less able, reducing the number of high quality individuals drafted. 4 Third, even if a draft brings in more able individuals, given the opportunity cost of these individuals, welfare may not be improved. 5 Finally, a draft has been compared to a low quality volunteer military, which is not the kind of military in the U.S. today. The main focus of this paper is to consider a theoretical model in which the military may tests individuals, excluding those with low ability. We compare a volunteer military with testing to two kinds of draft militaries, one with testing and one with a random draft (and no testing). We allow for the possibility some individuals may be able to fail the test, that is appear to be of less ability. The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. The outline of the model is in the next section. Although the main focus is on a military with testing, in Section 3, testing is ignored, and a random draft and a low quality volunteer military are compared. In Section 4, testing is introduced. Costly testing is considered in Section 5, and imprecise testing is the focus of Section 6. In Section 7, costly deferments and the deadweight loss from taxation are examined since they have been analyzed previously with homogeneous labor. The paper is summarized in Section Outline of the model The following are the basic assumptions of the model. The number of individuals available for work is normalized to one. 4 Richard Danzig (then assistant secretary of defense) argued, if the military tried to draft the top half of the ability distribution, You generate a lot of people who are trying to cheat, to appear to be not as good as they really are... (Danzig, 1982, p.110). 5 Berk and Lipow (forthcoming) note a draft may cause the enlistment of too many high quality individuals. Page 4 of 27

6 A fixed number of individuals, m, is required in the military in order for the military to produce. An individual s civilian quality/output is denoted by q, where q is uniformly distributed on [0,1]. In the military, individuals are either productive, with an individual output of k, or unproductive, with an output of zero. 6 Those who are productive in the military have q > q*, so the fraction of individuals who would be productive in the military 7 equals 1-q*. Except for in Section 7, lump sum taxation is assumed so there is no deadweight loss from taxation to pay military wages. If we assumed the military tried to attract m productive individuals in expectation, in some cases, more than m individuals would be enlisted. We assume the military is constrained to enlist exactly m individuals, and will attempt to get as many who are productive given that constraint. Assuming a fixed military productivity, k, for those with q > q* allows us to focus on which system, a draft or a volunteer military, obtains the largest number of high quality (productive) individuals, and what is the opportunity cost of those individuals. These assumptions allow those more able in civilian employment to be more productive in the military. Also, our assumptions imply welfare is higher if those with the lowest civilian output of those with q > q* are in the military. This is consistent with the idea the most productive individuals as civilians would be less productive in the military, k < 1, or, even if k > 1, it may be too costly to have those with the highest civilian productivity in the military. 6 We could assume unproductive individuals have some value in the military that is less than k. To simplify, we assume this value is zero, but m individuals still must be employed. Thus, individuals with q > q* have productivity of k each in the military provided there are m individuals in total enlisted. Additional individuals, regardless of q, have no value. 7 Ross (1990) also assumes a fraction of potential military personnel would be unproductive if enlisted. Page 5 of 27

7 More importantly, our assumptions are not critical to our results. The potential gain from a draft is it will enlist people who would not voluntarily enlist. Absent the cases listed below, we find a draft will not be able to increase welfare when the volunteer military is high quality--- designed to get, if possible, only those with q > q*. This would be true regardless of the assumptions of the how military output depends on q. We will see a draft can improve welfare only if 1) the volunteer military is low quality---takes those with the lowest civilian output, regardless of their military output; 2) testing is very costly; 3) testing is relatively imprecise; or 4) there is deadweight loss from taxation required to finance the military. In Section 4, we consider a costless and precise test except for the one possible error in testing discussed previously: those who do no want to serve in the military may fail the test and appear to be unproductive. Such behavior occurs only with a draft and testing. Let f equal the probability an individual who would otherwise pass the test may purposely fail. If the test is simply one s score on the Armed Forces Qualifications Test (AFQT), then f should equal one since anyone can fail if he so desires. However, the military can use as a test some combination of educational attainment and the AFQT score. In this case, even an intentionally low score on the AFQT may not preclude the military recognizing whether one would be productive if enlisted. Thus, we allow for the possibility f < A random draft vs. a low quality volunteer military Although our main focus is on a military when testing occurs, consider when a random draft would dominate a low-quality volunteer military (LQVM), that is when no testing occurs. 8 We will not consider the possibility one who is unproductive might pass the test, p. If only the AFQT were used, then, as argued in the text, f should equal one. In this case we could have p > 0. However, the more other measures of ability (such as education) are used, the less likely it is errors will be made, so both f and p should be reduced. If f is close to one, the draft can not dominate a volunteer military because more able individuals will all intentionally fail the test if drafted and paid less then their opportunity cost. Thus, we implicitly assume f is non-trivially lower than one, and assume p is low enough it can be ignored. Page 6 of 27

8 In order to allow the highest quality with a draft, it is assumed no volunteers are allowed when a draft is used. 9 In a draft (with no testing), m individuals are called at random, so the expected number of productive individuals in the military is m(1-q*). With q uniformally distributed between zero and one, the m individuals called have an expected civilian output of ½. Thus welfare with a random draft,, is: = m[(1-q*)k ½]. (1) For a random draft to be preferred to no military, (1-q*)k ½ > 0, or k >. (2) The RHS of ineq.(2) is minimized and equals ½ when q* = 0, so, for there to be any case for a random draft, we must have k > ½. In the rest of this paper, it is assumed ineq.(2) holds. If no testing is used, a volunteer military will set a wage equal to m and attract the m individuals with the lowest quality. If m < q*, no individual would be productive in the military with a volunteer system, and the draft would dominate a LQVM. If m > q*, then m-q* individuals will be productive in the military with a LQVM, and, with the average opportunity cost of the individuals enlisted equal to m/2, welfare would be: = (m-q*)k (3) 9 Beginning in 1918, no volunteers were allowed in World War One (Chambers, 1987). Page 7 of 27

9 Using eqs.(1) and (3), a LQVM is socially preferable to a random draft if: kq* <. (4) Assuming ineq.(2) holds (a random draft is preferable to no military), with m < 1, if fewer than 50% of the pool of potential military manpower would be productive if enlisted (q* > ½), then a draft is socially preferable to a LQVM (since k > ½). It is not clear whether q* ½ because of the uncertain size of the actual military labor pool. Some evidence may help illuminate the issue. Recent testimony by the Director for Accession Policy for the Department of Defense (Gilroy, 2009) shows, for fiscal year 2009, almost 85% of the 31 million individuals in the U.S. who were ages were unfit for military service, but this still left almost 5 million individuals, with the number of new enlistees desired less than 200,000 per year. For 2008, for all services, 92% of new recruits were high school graduates, and 69% scored in the top half of the Armed Forces Qualification Test. Also, the population ages is expected to grow from 31 million to 35 million by Thus, if the entire population of individuals in the relevant age group is the potential military labor pool, then q* > ½. However, if we restrict the pool to those who would not be deferred, then q* < ½. Also, it appears there are more productive individuals than the military desires, so m < 1 q*. However, we will consider the case when m > 1 q* in the Appendix. From ineq.(4), a random draft is more likely to be preferred to a LQVM the larger are k and q* and the smaller is m. With a random draft, the number of productive individuals in the military is m(1-q*). Assuming m > q*, then m-q* individuals are productive with a LQVM. More Page 8 of 27

10 individuals are productive with a random draft than with a LQVM if m < 1. Therefore, an increase in the value of a productive individual in the military, k, increases welfare with a random draft more than it does with a LQVM. Note, a wartime situation may suggest an increase in k. If that is true, a random draft is more likely to be socially preferable to a LQVM in wartime. An increase in q* reduces the number of productive individuals in the military, but does so one for one with a LQVM and only by 1-m for a unit increase in q* with a random draft. Thus, a random draft is more likely to be socially preferable to a LQVM as q* increases. An increase in m increases the number of productive individuals one for one with a LQVM, but only increases the number of productive individuals with a random draft by 1-q*, so a larger m implies a random draft is less likely to be preferred to a LQVM. The result a larger military implies a random draft is less likely to be preferred to a LQVM is the opposite of what has been found with homogeneous military quality (Johnson, 1990, Lee and McKenzie, 1992, Ross, 1994, Warner and Negrusa, 2005, and Perri, 2009). However, the previous studies all compared the reduced deadweight loss from taxation with a draft (due to a lower military wage) to other costs of a draft, with the former more important the larger the military. Since a random draft results in more individuals who are productive in the military, a LQVM can only dominate a random draft because the former involves a lower opportunity cost. For example, suppose k = 1, q* =.2, and m =.5. Now military output equals the number of individuals in the military who are productive (since k = 1), and this number is.4 with a random draft and.3 with a LQVM. The opportunity cost of the military equals.25 with a random draft (m/2) and.125 with a LQVM (m 2 /2). Thus, welfare is higher with the LQVM than with a random Page 9 of 27

11 draft versus.15. Although a random draft means more military output than with a LQVM, it does not necessarily mean higher welfare. 4. Testing: a high quality volunteer military is possible Consider the possibility of testing individuals to see if they will be productive in the military. Ross (1990) assumes quality is observable at induction centers via tests. Berck and Lipow (forthcoming) argue quality is unobservable prior to enlistment. We assume the test is some combination of one s educational record and one s score on an entrance exam such as the AFQT. Assume (for now) the test is costless and is accurate except for the possibility an individual who tries to fail is able to do so with a probability of f, with f independent of q. Thus, with a volunteer military or a draft, the military can costlessly call individuals, test them, and see who passes. Assume there is a sufficient number of productive individuals to satisfy the military s demand, or m < 1-q*. The possibility m > 1-q* is considered in the Appendix. We will compare a high-quality volunteer military (HQVM) to a random draft and to a draft with testing. First, we determine whether a HQVM dominates a LQVM. Welfare with a LQVM is given by eq.(3). With a HQVM, the wage is set to just attract the m productive individuals who have the lowest opportunity cost. 10 Thus the wage will equal q*+m, and only those who are tested and found to be productive are enlisted---those with q[q*, q*+m]. The average opportunity cost of those enlisted is then q*+. Thus, welfare with a HQVM is: =. (5) 10 If k is small enough, welfare will be higher if the military sets a lower wage and attracts fewer than m productive individuals. However, the choice of a welfare-maximizing wage does not change the essential results, as shown in the Appendix. Page 10 of 27

12 Using eqs.(3) and (5), a HQVM is preferred to a LQVM if k > m. A HQVM dominates a LQVM if the marginal (and average) value of a productive individual in the military exceeds the opportunity cost of the most able (in civilian output) individual enlisted with a LQVM. In order to meaningfully compare a HQVM with a draft, it is assumed k > m. 11 First, we consider a draft with testing. With, w d the wage with a draft, individuals who are called and have q > w d will try to fail the test. The number who pass the test who will be productive in the military is then: max(0, w d -q*) + (1-f)(1-w d ). (6) If w d > q*, there are w d - q* individuals who will be productive in the military and who will not try to fail the test. If w d < q*, all those who would be productive in the military will try to fail the test. Thus, if the military places even a trivial on keeping its payroll cost as low as possible, it should either set w d equal to zero or set w d > q* so m individuals pass the test. If (1-f)(1-q*) > m, there are enough productive individuals who pass the test if w d = 0. For now consider the case when (1-f)(1-q*) < m, so, assuming w d > q*, we use eq.(6), to get m productive individuals in the military. Solving for w d : w d = 1. (7) Page 11 of 27 Note lim = m+q*---the wage with a HQVM---and > 1. If everyone who wishes to fail the test can do so, then f = 1. As f is reduced from one, w d is reduced because the 11 We know k > ½ from the condition for a random draft to be preferred to military (ineq.(2)). Thus, if the military requires less than ½ of the eligible population, k > m.

13 draft brings in more individuals who would prefer not to serve (q > w d ) and who are productive. Note that a lower f reduces welfare since higher opportunity cost individuals who are productive serve in the military instead of lower opportunity cost individuals (some with q* < q < w d ). Given m < 1-q*, with either a draft and testing or a HQVM, all m individuals who are enlisted are productive. With a HQVM, the opportunity cost is m(q*+ ). With a draft and testing, there are w d - q* individuals who willingly are drafted, and who have an average opportunity cost of, and there are (1-f)(1-w d ) individuals who try to fail the test but do not, and who have an average opportunity cost of, so, using eq.(7), the opportunity cost of a draft with testing is given by: OC draft/testing = (8) It is easy to see lim / = m(q*+ )---the opportunity cost with a HQVM---and / < 0. If all who want to fail the test do so (f = 1), the draft and a HQVM pay the same wage and enlist exactly the same individuals, those with q[q*, q*+m]. If f < 1, some higher opportunity cost individuals replace lower opportunity cost individuals with a draft so the draft implies lower welfare than with a HQVM. Now suppose m < (1-f)(1-q*). Thus, a sufficient number of productive individuals who will not fail the test exist so, with a draft and testing, the military can set w d = 0 and induct at random m of those who pass the test (since it is assumed the military does not observe q). The average opportunity cost of those inducted with a draft is, so welfare with a draft is Page 12 of 27

14 m(k ). Using eq.(5), welfare with a draft exceeds that with a HQVM only if < q*+, or if q*+ m > 1, which is not true in this case. Thus, at least for the case when m < 1-q*, a draft with testing can not increase welfare in comparison with a HQVM, and will reduce welfare if some individuals who wish to fail military testing can not do so (f < 1). 12 With m < 1-q*, we have seen a HQVM is socially preferable to a draft with testing. We now consider whether a HQVM dominates a random draft when the latter involves no testing. Using eqs.(1) and (5), A HQVM dominates a random draft if: > q*(1-k). (9) Clearly, if k > 1, a HQVM dominates a random draft. Also, a HQVM is less likely to dominate a random draft the larger is m. Since m < 1-q*, substitute 1-q* for m in ineq.(9), and the inequality becomes k > ½, which, from the previous section, must hold in order for a random draft to be preferred to no military. Therefore, at least for the case of a relatively small military, m < 1-q*, a HQM is socially preferable to either a random draft or a draft with testing. As shown in the Appendix, with a large military, m > 1-q*, we also find higher welfare with a HQVM than with either a random draft or a draft with testing. Thus, absent costly or imprecise testing, a military forced to enlsit the lowest quality individuals, or deadweight loss from taxation, a draft can not improve and generally reduces welfare relative to a volunteer military. The intuitive reason for this is simple. As long as a volunteer military enlists only the high quality individuals with the lowest opportunity cost, welfare can not be increased with an alternative enlistment method. 12 One advantage of the draft with testing is the lower wage may imply a lower deadweight loss from taxation, which, as noted in Section 1, is assumed away in most of this paper, but is considered in Section 7. Page 13 of 27

15 5. Costly testing We now consider costs of testing individuals. Suppose testing costs c per individual for the military, where c is assumed to be both a social and private cost. The interesting case is when we compare a HQVM to a military with a random draft (no testing). For brevity, we will consider only the case when m < 1 q*. Now welfare with a HQVM is: =, (10) since the military sets w v = q* + m, and that is the number who apply and are tested. Using eq.(1), a HQVM is preferred to a random draft if: > q*(1 k) + (q* + m)c. (11) From ineq.(11), a HQVM is less likely to dominate a random draft the larger is m. Since m < 1 q*, in order to have the least chance a HQVM dominates a random draft, substitute 1 q* for m in ineq.(11), and we have: q*(k ½) > c. (12) To appreciate the magnitudes involved, even with m as large as possible (so a HQVM is least likely to dominate a random draft), suppose q* = ½, so 50% of potential inductees would be productive. From the discussion in Section 3, an expansive view of the potential military labor pool would suggest q* is relatively low (1 q* is relatively high). Also, from ineq.(2), if q* = ½, Page 14 of 27

16 k > 1. Now, if k = 1, as long as the cost of testing is less than ½ the civilian output of the least able individual who would be productive in the military (one with q = q*), a HQVM would dominate a draft. Thus, without very high testing cost, it is unlikely a random draft would be preferred to a HQVM. 6. Imperfect testing We now consider a test that is costless but imperfect. Suppose, as before, there are enough individuals in the population who would be productive in the military so m < 1-q*. The test is imperfect because all those with q > pass, and 0 < < q*. Also, as before, we assume the military must have m individuals. We assume the military is constrained to offer the lowest wage that will attract m individuals who pass, knowing not all of them will be productive. Note, if we allowed for a higher wage, we would get excess supply of applicants who pass the test. Choosing them at random would imply more who are productive (have q > q*), and also a higher opportunity cost. With w set to just attract m who pass the test, w = + m. The number enlisted who are productive in the military is then + m q*. For this number to be positive, regardless of how small is, that is, even if = 0 (all pass), m > q*. Combined with the assumption m < 1-q*, we then must have q* < ½: more than ½ of the population would be productive in the military. In the rest of this section, it is assumed q* < ½. With a volunteer military, those with civilian productivity from to + m are enlisted, so their average opportunity cost is +. Welfare with a HQVM is then:. = k( + m q*) m( + ). (13) Page 15 of 27

17 Welfare with a random draft, RD, was found before (eq. (1)), and equals RD = m[(1-q*)k ½], so a HQVM is preferred to a random draft if: k[ - q*(1-m)] > m{- ½(1-m)]. (14) Call the left and right hand sides of ineq.(14) LHS 14 and RHS 14. Now LHS 14 is the value of military output with a HQVM minus the same thing with a random draft, and RHS 14 is the opportunity cost of a HQVM minus the opportunity cost of a random draft. There are four possibilities, depending on the value of. Case 1. = 0. This is the same as when we have a low-quality volunteer military, LQVM, and, as seen before, a LQVM dominates a random draft only if k <. Note, as discussed in Section 3, a larger military implies it is more likely a LQVM is preferable to a random draft. Case 2. 0 < < q*(1-m). A HQVM has higher welfare than a random draft if, using ineq.(14): k <. (15) Note, with q* < ½, both the numerator and the denominator of the RHS of ineq.(15) are negative since < q*(1-m). Now LHS 14 and RHS 14 are both negative. There are more individuals who are productive in the military with a random draft than with a HQVM, but the Page 16 of 27

18 latter has a lower opportunity cost. As in Case 1, only if the value of a productive individual in the military, k, is low enough would a HQVM have higher welfare than a random draft. Case 3. q*(1-m) < <. Now LHS 14 > 0 and RHS 14 < 0: a HQVM attracts more individuals who are productive in the military than would a random draft, and does so at a lower opportunity cost than with a random draft. Thus, for any k > 0, a HQVM yields higher welfare than with a random draft. Case 4. < < q*. Intuitively, the larger is, the more likely a HQVM yields higher welfare than a random draft would. Thus, with a HQVM unambiguously involving higher welfare than a random draft when q*(1-m) < <, one might think it is obvious a HQVM has higher welfare when >. However, in this case, both LHS 14 and RHS 14 are positive: compared to a random, a HQVM attracts more individuals who are able, but does so at a higher opportunity cost. A HQVM has higher welfare than a random draft if: k >, (16) where both the numerator and the denominator of the RHS of ineq.(16) are now positive. The RHS of ineq.(16) is increasing in. If we let = q*, we have a HQVM with perfect and costless testing, which was shown in Section 4 to have higher welfare than a random draft. Thus, a HQVM yield higher welfare than a random draft if q*(1-m) <. Page 17 of 27

19 Now we have two possibilities for a HQVM with imprecise testing to have higher welfare than a random draft. First, use the result a HQVM is preferred if q*(1-m) <. This term can be rearranged to get: m > i. (17) Now i is in index of the inaccuracy of the test. If the test is perfectly accurate, = q* and i = 0. If the test is perfectly inaccurate, = 0, and i = 1. The results for this section suggest the following. Proposition One. A high quality volunteer military with imprecise testing results in higher welfare than a random draft if a) the inaccuracy rate of the test is less than the share of the population desired in the military, m > i; or b) if m < i, the value of a productive individual in the military, k, is low enough. If m < i, then < q*(1-m), which is Case 2 from above when a HQVM attracts fewer individuals who are productive, but at a lower opportunity cost, than does a random draft. Then only if productive individuals have a value in the military that is low enough (ineq.(15)) would a HQVM have higher welfare than a random draft. For m > i, a HQVM attracts more individuals who are productive than does a draft. In that case, despite the possibility of a higher opportunity cost with a HQVM than with a random draft---which occurs if < ---welfare is larger with a HQVM than with a random draft. As with the case with a LQVM, with imprecise testing, the larger the military, the more likely the volunteer military is preferable to a random draft. 7. Deferments and deadweight loss from taxation Page 18 of 27

20 Until now we have ignored aspects of the draft versus a volunteer military that have previously been considered. Johnson (1990), Lee and McKenzie (1992) and Ross (1994) have argued the deadweight loss (DWL) from taxation may result in a lower social cost for the draft than with a volunteer military. In response, Warner and Asch (1996) noted the reduced productivity of draftees relative to volunteers, Warner and Negrusa (2005) compared the costs of draft evasion and DWL from taxation, and Perri (2010) considered the tradeoff between the DWL of taxation and the social cost of deferments when individuals can incur costs to attain a deferred status. Although these issues are independent of the problem of the quality of military personnel and have been considered elsewhere, we will now briefly consider DWL and deferments. Suppose the test is costless and precise (and no one can fail the test who would be productive in the military, f = 0), but all can obtain a deferment at a cost (social and private) of D. 13 The DWL from taxation = t[military wage payments], where t is assumed to be constant and is the DWL rate per dollar of military payroll. We also assume k = 1, so all are more valuable in the military, provided the military enlists n individuals and n < m; m < 1-q*, so the military can attract m productive individuals; and testing is costless. Thus, we have the HQVM from Section 4: the volunteer wage equals q*+m, and individuals with q[q*, q*+m] are enlisted. With a draft and testing, assume the military sets the wage, w d, to just attract the same individuals as with a HQVM (recall the assumption no one can fail the test), so there is no misallocation from the wrong individuals being in the military. The tradeoff here is between lower DWL with a draft and the cost of deferments. Those with 13 Examples of deferments are given in Perri (2010). Page 19 of 27

21 q D > w d will purchase a deferment 14. Thus, if the military sets w d = q*+m D, 15 those with q > q*+m will obtain deferments, those with q < q* will be discharged after testing, and those with q[q*, q*+m] will be enlisted. The reduced DWL from a draft is the DWL rate (t) multiplied by the lower wage (D) and the number enlisted (m). The cost of deferments is D times the number who defer (1 m q*). Thus a HQVM is preferred to a draft if: t <. (18) Ineq.(18) is similar to the result in Perri (2010), who finds, in a model with homogeneous labor, a fairly large military force relative to the military labor pool would be required for the DWL from taxation to be sufficiently large so as to offset the cost of deferments. It is possible World War Two involved a large enough demand for military personnel the draft might have been comparable to a volunteer military in social cost. 16 Using ineq.(18), and are both negative. Thus, the greater the demand for military personnel (dm > 0), and the fewer individuals who would be productive in the military (dq* > 0), the less likely is a HQVM to be preferred to a random draft. Increases in either m or q* imply fewer individuals will choose to incur the cost to be deferred, and a larger m also means a larger savings in the wage bill with a draft, and thus even lower DWL with a draft versus a volunteer military. 14 Deferments act like buyouts that were available in the U.S. Civil War, except the latter involved no social costs. For analysis of the U.S. Civil War draft, see Perri (2008). 15 Paying a lower wage with a draft would result in more deferring and the military attracting fewer than m productive individuals. 16 As is the case herein, Perri (2010) ignores some costs of the draft relative to a volunteer military, such as higher turnover and reduced effort. Page 20 of 27

22 8. Summary It has been argued the draft may enable the military to attract more able individuals than a volunteer military and thus increase welfare. In our theoretical model, we find this may be the case if a volunteer military simply takes the least able individuals. However, when the military tests individuals and does not take the lowest quality applicants, neither a random draft nor a draft with testing increases welfare, and both usually decrease welfare---assuming a costless and precise test, and ignoring deadweight loss from taxation. When there is a sufficient number of productive individuals available to the military, and testing would be used by both a volunteer military and a draft, the same number of productive individuals are attracted with either system, but a draft involves a higher opportunity cost. When the military can not attract the desired number of productive individuals, a draft may attract more individuals who are productive than would a volunteer military, but the higher opportunity cost of the former leads to lower welfare with a draft versus a volunteer military. With either a low quality volunteer military or a high quality volunteer military with imprecise testing, the larger the size of the military, the more likely welfare is higher with a volunteer military than with a draft. This is the opposite of what is found in models of homogeneous labor quality, when the deadweight loss from taxation is considered (Johnson, 1990, Lee and McKenzie, 1992, Ross, 1994, Warner and Asch, 1996, and Perri, 2010). However, when testing is costly, the larger the military, the less likely it is a volunteer military will have higher welfare than a random draft since the latter does not involve testing. In general with heterogenous labor quality and deadweight loss from taxation, the effect of military size on the relative efficiency of the draft an a volunteer military is ambiguous. Page 21 of 27

23 Compare the results herein to those in Birchenall and Koch (2011). They focus on selection bias in a Roy model of self-selection. With perfect information (analogous to our model when testing is costless and precise), they find similar welfare effects to those found herein if military and civilian productivity are positively associated. This suggests our assumption of constant military productivity does not drive our results. Birchenall and Koch do not look at welfare effects unless they are obvious, say, when military and civilian output are both higher with a volunteer military. Also, with imprecise testing, we find a draft could have either higher or lower civilian and military output than with a high quality volunteer, even with a positive association between military and civilian output. In general, we find a random draft would dominate a volunteer military with testing (that is, a high quality military) only if testing is relatively costly or imprecise, or, as has been previously demonstrated, if the deadweight loss from taxation to support the military is sufficiently high. Page 22 of 27

24 Appendix The case of a relatively large military (m >1-q*) If m > 1-q*, there are not enough productive individuals to satisfy the military s demand. As suggested in Section 3, this does not appear to be the case in the U.S. today. However, continued increases in the fraction of the U.S. population who are obese or otherwise unfit, accompanied by an unexpected increase in the desired size of the U.S. military, could result in such a situation. Also, for a county like Israel, this case may be relevant today. With a draft and testing, the number of productive individuals obtained is again given by eq.(6). If w d > q*, the average opportunity cost of those in the military for the w d - q* individuals who do not try to fail the test is, and the average opportunity cost of the (1-f)(1-w d ) individuals who try to fail but do not is. Welfare with a draft and testing, /, is then: / = k[w d q* + (1-f)(1-w d )] ½[(w d q*)(w d + q*) + (1-f)(1-w d )(1+w d )]. (A1) In this case, the military must choose the wage, 17 given a higher wage will yield more in the military---because those willing to serve increase one for one with a wage increase, and those who do not want to serve decrease by 1-f for each unit increase in the wage---but will also increase the average opportunity cost of both types who are enlisted. The welfare-maximizing wage is determined by: / = f(k w d ) = 0. (A2) From eq.(a2), we can conclude w d = min(1,k). If k < 1, w d = k, and, if k > 1, w d = 1, since that is the highest wage anyone would earn in the civilian sector (when q = 1). 18 With a HQVM, and a wage equal to w v, the number of productive individuals attracted is w v q*, and these individuals have an average opportunity cost of. Thus, with a volunteer military, the welfare-maximizing wage is determined by maximizing : =, (A3) = k w v. (A4) Thus, w v = w d = min(1,k). With a draft and testing, if w d is set above q*, so not all productive individuals will try to fail the test, a draft and a volunteer military set identical wages. 17 As noted in the Section 4, we could have considered the optimal choice of the military wage when m < 1 q*. In this Appendix, it is shown the results are similar when the military wage is chosen to maximize welfare and when it is assumed to be set to enlist as many productive individuals as possible in the military, provided the number does not exceed m. 18 We assume k > q*. If this is not true, then no productive individuals would be enlisted with a HQVM. Page 23 of 27

25 Letting w d = w v = k, with k > q* (or else no productive individuals would be enlisted with a HQVM), substitute in eqs.(a1) and (A3) for w d and w v. We find a HQVM is preferred to a draft with testing if: (1 - f)(1 + k 2 ) > 2k(1 - f) + 2q*(q* - k). (A5) With k > q*, the second term on RHS (A5) is negative. Thus, if LHS (A5) exceeds the first term on RHS (A5), ineq.(a5) holds. This simplifies to k 2 2k + 1 z > 0. Now = 2(k 1), and = 2. The minimum value of z occurs when k = 1 and z = 0. Thus, z > 0, with the strict inequality holding when k 1. Since the second term on the RHS (14) is negative, clearly ineq.(a5) holds and the HQVM dominates the draft in this case. With w d = w v = k < 1, a HQVM enlists k q* productive individuals, and (using eq.(6)) a draft with testing enlists k q* + (1 f)(1 k) individuals. However, the draft brings in higher opportunity cost individuals for whom it is not socially optimal to be enlisted. Although a military with the draft is assumed to choose the wage that maximizes welfare, this maximization occurs given that reluctant individuals who do not fail the test will be inducted. A volunteer military accounts for the opportunity cost of all individuals inducted when the wage is chosen. If k > 1, w d = w v = 1. In this case, it is optimal to have all 1 q* productive individuals in the military, and a draft and a HQVM would be identical. Now consider whether a HQVM is preferred to a random draft when no testing is used in the latter. Consider the case where the volunteer wage equals one (k > 1). 19 Using eq.(a3), welfare with the HQVM is then (1 q*)(k ), and welfare from a random draft is given by eq.(1). The HQVM is preferred to a random draft if: (1 q*)(1 m)k > ½[(1 q*)(1 + q*) m]. (A6) Both sides of ineq.(a6) are linear and decreasing in m. If m = 1, LHS (15) = 0, and RHS (15) = -½[q*] 2. Since m > 1 q* in this case, the smallest value of m is slightly larger than 1 q*. Substituting 1 q* in ineq.(a6) for m yields LHS (A6) = k q*(1 q*) and RHS (A6) = ½ q*(1 q*). Since we must have k > ½, the HQVM dominates a random draft for all m > 1 q*. Now, with a draft and testing, as discussed in Section 4, it may be optimal to set w d = 0. Then no productive individual wishes to be in the military. Now the number of productive individuals inducted equals (1 f)(1 q*), and the average opportunity cost of those attracted is. Thus, using eq.(a3) with w v = 1, it is easy to see the draft has the same average opportunity cost as a HQVM, but attracts fewer productive individuals, and thus is dominated by a HQVM. 19 When w v = k, the HQVM dominates a random draft if (k-q*) 2 > m[2(1-q*)k 1]. This is least likely to hold the larger is m, so let m = 1. The inequality then becomes k 2 + [q*] 2 > 2k - 1. Since ½ < k < 1 in this case, let k = ½ +, 0 < < ½. Then the inequality becomes ¼ + [q*] 2 > (1-). The RHS of the inequality is maximized when = ½, yielding a RHS = ¼. Thus, the HQVM dominates a random draft in this case. Note, we assumed previously k > m (in order for a HQVM to dominate a LQVM), but that is irrelevant for the proof in this footnote since we simply needed to show a HQVM dominates a random draft when w v =k. Page 24 of 27

26 When w v = k, welfare with a high quality volunteer military (HQVM) is given by eq.(a3) with w v = k, and equals ½(k q*) 2. With a draft, (1 f)(1 q*) productive individuals are inducted, with an average opportunity cost of, so welfare with a draft is (1 f)(1 q*)(k - ). The HQVM is preferred to the draft if (simplifying terms): k 2 2kq* + [q*] 2 > (1 f)(1 q*)(2k 1 q*). (A7) If LHS (A1) > (1 q*)(2k 1 q*), then LHS (A1) > RHS (A1). This occurs if k 2 2k + 1 > 0, which was shown to be true in the proof following ineq.(a5) above. In Section 4 and in this Appendix, we found neither a draft with testing nor a random draft ever dominates a HQVM when testing is costless and precise. When the military is relatively small (m < 1 q*), the draft attracts the same number of productive individuals as does a HQVM, but at a higher opportunity cost. With a larger military (m >1 q*), the draft may result in more of the productive individuals enlisted, but at an opportunity cost sufficiently high so welfare is reduced. Page 25 of 27

27 References Asch, Beth, Romley, John A., and Totten, Mark E. The Quality of Personnel in the Enlisted Ranks. Report, the Rand Corporation, Becker, Gary S. The Case Against Conscription. Working paper # D-4514, the Rand Corporation, Berck, Peter, and Lipow, Jonathan. Military Conscription and the (Socially) Optimal Number of Boots on the Ground. Southern Economic Journal, forthcoming. Birchenall, Javier B., and Koch, Thomas G. Gallantry in Action : Evidence of Favorable Selection in a Volunteer Military. Working paper, University of California at Santa Barbara, April 21, Chambers, John W. II. To Raise an Army. London: The Free Press, Danzig, Richard. Dinner Speech. In Registration and the Draft, ed. by Martin Anderson, Palo Alto: Hoover Institution, Gilroy, Curtis. Recruiting, Retention, and End Strength Overview. Testimony before the House Armed Services Personnel Subcommittee, March 3, Hosek, James R., and Mattock, Michael G. Learning About Quality: How the Quality of Military Personnel is Revealed Over Time. Report, the Rand Corporation, Hosek, James R.; Mattock, Michael G.; Fair, C. Christine; Kavanagh, Jennifer; Sharp, Jennifer; and Totten, Mark. Attracting the Best: How the Military Competes for Information Technology Personnel. Report, the Rand Corporation, Johnson, William R. When is a Military Draft Optimal? Working paper, University of Virginia, Lee, Dwight R., and McKenzie, Richard B. Reexamination of the Relative Efficiency of the Draft and the All-Volunteer Army. Southern Economic Journal 58 (January 1992): Perri, Timothy J. The Economics of US Civil War Conscription. American Law and Economics Review 10 (Fall 2008): Deferments and the Relative Cost of Conscription. BEPress Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy: Topics 10 (Issue ): article 103. Pirie, Robert B., Jr. Enlistment Mental Testing. Memorandum for the Secretary of Defense, February 13, Page 26 of 27

28 Ross, Thomas W. Raising an Army: A Positive Theory of Military Recruitment. Working paper, Carleton University, Raising an Army: A Positive Theory of Military Recruitment. Journal of Law and Economics 37 (April 1994): Warner, John T., and Asch, Beth J. The Economic Theory of a Military Draft Reconsidered. Defence and Peace Economics 7 (Issue ): Warner, John T., and Negrusa, Sebastian. Evasion Costs and the Theory of Conscription. Defence and Peace Economics 16 (April 2005): Page 27 of 27

2. The model 2.1. Basic variables

2. The model 2.1. Basic variables 1. Introduction Recent research has shown how military conscription---the draft---can adversely affect individual investment in human capital investment. 1 However, human capital investment also occurs

More information

Department of Economics Working Paper

Department of Economics Working Paper Department of Economics Working Paper Number 11-15 September 2011 Can A Draft Induce More Human Capital Investment in the Military? Timothy Perri Appalachian State University Department of Economics Appalachian

More information

Quality of enlisted accessions

Quality of enlisted accessions Quality of enlisted accessions Military active and reserve components need to attract not only new recruits, but also high quality new recruits. However, measuring qualifications for military service,

More information

INCENTIVES TO TRANSFER PATIENTS UNDER ALTERNATIVE REIMBURSEMENT MECHANISMS

INCENTIVES TO TRANSFER PATIENTS UNDER ALTERNATIVE REIMBURSEMENT MECHANISMS INCENTIVES TO TRANSFER PATIENTS UNDER ALTERNATIVE REIMBURSEMENT MECHANISMS By: Randall P. Ellis and Christopher J. Ruhm Incentives to Transfer Patients Under Alternative Reimbursement Mechanisms (with

More information

The Economics of US Civil War Conscription

The Economics of US Civil War Conscription The Economics of US Civil War Conscription by Timothy J. Perri* May, 006 *Professor of Economics, Appalachian State University, Boone, NC 8608. E-mail: {perritj@appstate.edu}. JEL classifications: N11,

More information

Population Representation in the Military Services

Population Representation in the Military Services Population Representation in the Military Services Fiscal Year 2008 Report Summary Prepared by CNA for OUSD (Accession Policy) Population Representation in the Military Services Fiscal Year 2008 Report

More information

Specialist Payment Schemes and Patient Selection in Private and Public Hospitals. Donald J. Wright

Specialist Payment Schemes and Patient Selection in Private and Public Hospitals. Donald J. Wright Specialist Payment Schemes and Patient Selection in Private and Public Hospitals Donald J. Wright December 2004 Abstract It has been observed that specialist physicians who work in private hospitals are

More information

An Evaluation of URL Officer Accession Programs

An Evaluation of URL Officer Accession Programs CAB D0017610.A2/Final May 2008 An Evaluation of URL Officer Accession Programs Ann D. Parcell 4825 Mark Center Drive Alexandria, Virginia 22311-1850 Approved for distribution: May 2008 Henry S. Griffis,

More information

The Economics of U.S. Civil War Conscription

The Economics of U.S. Civil War Conscription The Economics of U.S. Civil War Conscription by Timothy J. Perri* December 0, 007 *Professor of Economics, Appalachian State University, Boone, NC 8608. E-mail: {perritj@appstate.edu}. I thank Dennis Carlton

More information

Unemployment. Rongsheng Tang. August, Washington U. in St. Louis. Rongsheng Tang (Washington U. in St. Louis) Unemployment August, / 44

Unemployment. Rongsheng Tang. August, Washington U. in St. Louis. Rongsheng Tang (Washington U. in St. Louis) Unemployment August, / 44 Unemployment Rongsheng Tang Washington U. in St. Louis August, 2016 Rongsheng Tang (Washington U. in St. Louis) Unemployment August, 2016 1 / 44 Overview Facts The steady state rate of unemployment Types

More information

The Effect of Enlistment Bonuses on First-Term Tenure Among Navy Enlistees

The Effect of Enlistment Bonuses on First-Term Tenure Among Navy Enlistees CRM D0006014.A2/Final April 2003 The Effect of Enlistment Bonuses on First-Term Tenure Among Navy Enlistees Gerald E. Cox with Ted M. Jaditz and David L. Reese 4825 Mark Center Drive Alexandria, Virginia

More information

GAO MILITARY ATTRITION. Better Screening of Enlisted Personnel Could Save DOD Millions of Dollars

GAO MILITARY ATTRITION. Better Screening of Enlisted Personnel Could Save DOD Millions of Dollars GAO United States General Accounting Office Testimony Before the Subcommittee on Personnel, Committee on Armed Services, U.S. Senate For Release on Delivery Expected at 2:00 p.m., EDT Wednesday, March

More information

The Economics of US Civil War Conscription

The Economics of US Civil War Conscription American Law and Economics Review Advance Access published December 4, 2008 The Economics of US Civil War Conscription Timothy J. Perri, Appalachian State University US conscription in the Civil War is

More information

Report on the Pilot Survey on Obtaining Occupational Exposure Data in Interventional Cardiology

Report on the Pilot Survey on Obtaining Occupational Exposure Data in Interventional Cardiology Report on the Pilot Survey on Obtaining Occupational Exposure Data in Interventional Cardiology Working Group on Interventional Cardiology (WGIC) Information System on Occupational Exposure in Medicine,

More information

Reenlistment Rates Across the Services by Gender and Race/Ethnicity

Reenlistment Rates Across the Services by Gender and Race/Ethnicity Issue Paper #31 Retention Reenlistment Rates Across the Services by Gender and Race/Ethnicity MLDC Research Areas Definition of Diversity Legal Implications Outreach & Recruiting Leadership & Training

More information

For More Information

For More Information CHILDREN AND FAMILIES EDUCATION AND THE ARTS ENERGY AND ENVIRONMENT HEALTH AND HEALTH CARE INFRASTRUCTURE AND TRANSPORTATION INTERNATIONAL AFFAIRS LAW AND BUSINESS NATIONAL SECURITY POPULATION AND AGING

More information

H ipl»r>rt lor potxue WIWM r Q&ftultod

H ipl»r>rt lor potxue WIWM r Q&ftultod GAO United States General Accounting Office Washington, D.C. 20548 National Security and International Affairs Division B-270643 January 6,1997 The Honorable Dirk Kempthorne Chairman The Honorable Robert

More information

PEONIES Member Interviews. State Fiscal Year 2012 FINAL REPORT

PEONIES Member Interviews. State Fiscal Year 2012 FINAL REPORT PEONIES Member Interviews State Fiscal Year 2012 FINAL REPORT Report prepared for the Wisconsin Department of Health Services Office of Family Care Expansion by Sara Karon, PhD, PEONIES Project Director

More information

Partial Privatization and Subsidization in a Mixed Duopoly: R&D versus Output

Partial Privatization and Subsidization in a Mixed Duopoly: R&D versus Output Partial Privatization and Subsidization in a Mixed Duopoly: R&D versus Output Subsidies Sang-Ho Lee Graduate School of Economics, Chonnam National University, Korea Timur K. Muminov Graduate School of

More information

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Military Service and Civilian Earnings of Youths

Volume URL:  Chapter Title: Military Service and Civilian Earnings of Youths This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Public Sector Payrolls Volume Author/Editor: David A. Wise, ed. Volume Publisher: University

More information

Getting the right case in the right room at the right time is the goal for every

Getting the right case in the right room at the right time is the goal for every OR throughput Are your operating rooms efficient? Getting the right case in the right room at the right time is the goal for every OR director. Often, though, defining how well the OR suite runs depends

More information

Recruiting in the 21st Century: Technical Aptitude and the Navy's Requirements. Jennie W. Wenger Zachary T. Miller Seema Sayala

Recruiting in the 21st Century: Technical Aptitude and the Navy's Requirements. Jennie W. Wenger Zachary T. Miller Seema Sayala Recruiting in the 21st Century: Technical Aptitude and the Navy's Requirements Jennie W. Wenger Zachary T. Miller Seema Sayala CRM D0022305.A2/Final May 2010 Approved for distribution: May 2010 Henry S.

More information

Are physicians ready for macra/qpp?

Are physicians ready for macra/qpp? Are physicians ready for macra/qpp? Results from a KPMG-AMA Survey kpmg.com ama-assn.org Contents Summary Executive Summary 2 Background and Survey Objectives 5 What is MACRA? 5 AMA and KPMG collaboration

More information

Most surgical facilities in the US perform all

Most surgical facilities in the US perform all ECONOMICS AND HEALTH SYSTEMS RESEARCH SECTION EDITOR RONALD D. MILLER Changing Allocations of Operating Room Time From a System Based on Historical Utilization to One Where the Aim is to Schedule as Many

More information

The Prior Service Recruiting Pool for National Guard and Reserve Selected Reserve (SelRes) Enlisted Personnel

The Prior Service Recruiting Pool for National Guard and Reserve Selected Reserve (SelRes) Enlisted Personnel Issue Paper #61 National Guard & Reserve MLDC Research Areas The Prior Service Recruiting Pool for National Guard and Reserve Selected Reserve (SelRes) Enlisted Personnel Definition of Diversity Legal

More information

For More Information

For More Information THE ARTS CHILD POLICY CIVIL JUSTICE EDUCATION ENERGY AND ENVIRONMENT This PDF document was made available from www.rand.org as a public service of the RAND Corporation. Jump down to document6 HEALTH AND

More information

Working Paper Series

Working Paper Series The Financial Benefits of Critical Access Hospital Conversion for FY 1999 and FY 2000 Converters Working Paper Series Jeffrey Stensland, Ph.D. Project HOPE (and currently MedPAC) Gestur Davidson, Ph.D.

More information

Key findings. Jennie W. Wenger, Caolionn O Connell, Maria C. Lytell

Key findings. Jennie W. Wenger, Caolionn O Connell, Maria C. Lytell C O R P O R A T I O N Retaining the Army s Cyber Expertise Jennie W. Wenger, Caolionn O Connell, Maria C. Lytell Key findings Despite the restrictive requirements for qualification, the Army has a large

More information

GAO. DEFENSE BUDGET Trends in Reserve Components Military Personnel Compensation Accounts for

GAO. DEFENSE BUDGET Trends in Reserve Components Military Personnel Compensation Accounts for GAO United States General Accounting Office Report to the Chairman, Subcommittee on National Security, Committee on Appropriations, House of Representatives September 1996 DEFENSE BUDGET Trends in Reserve

More information

A Look At Cash Compensation for Active-Duty Military Personnel

A Look At Cash Compensation for Active-Duty Military Personnel A Look At Cash Compensation for Active-Duty Military Personnel Beth J. Asch James R. Hosek Craig W. Martin Prepared for the Office of the Secretary of Defense R National Defense Research Institute Approved

More information

Introduction and Executive Summary

Introduction and Executive Summary Introduction and Executive Summary 1. Introduction and Executive Summary. Hospital length of stay (LOS) varies markedly and persistently across geographic areas in the United States. This phenomenon is

More information

Department of Defense INSTRUCTION

Department of Defense INSTRUCTION Department of Defense INSTRUCTION NUMBER 1205.21 September 20, 1999 USD(P&R) SUBJECT: Reserve Component Incentive Programs Procedures References: (a) DoD Directive 1205.21, "Reserve Component Incentive

More information

Department of Defense DIRECTIVE. SUBJECT: Enlistment and Reenlistment Bonuses for Active Members

Department of Defense DIRECTIVE. SUBJECT: Enlistment and Reenlistment Bonuses for Active Members Department of Defense DIRECTIVE NUMBER 1304.21 July 22, 1996 SUBJECT: Enlistment and Reenlistment Bonuses for Active Members Incorporating Change 1, January 20, 1998 ASD(FMP) References: (a) Sections 301c,

More information

A Report of The Heritage Center for Data Analysis

A Report of The Heritage Center for Data Analysis A Report of The Heritage Center for Data Analysis MORE H-1B VISAS, MORE AMERICAN JOBS, A BETTER ECONOMY JAMES SHERK AND GUINEVERE NELL CDA08-01 April 30, 2008 214 Massachusetts Avenue, NE Washington, D.C.

More information

FISCAL FEDERALISM. How State and Local Governments Differ from the National Government

FISCAL FEDERALISM. How State and Local Governments Differ from the National Government FISCAL FEDERALISM devolution: The passing or transferring of fiscal responsibilities and authority from one level of government to another. In August 1996, Congress approved legislation ending 60-year

More information

State of Kansas Department of Social and Rehabilitation Services Department on Aging Kansas Health Policy Authority

State of Kansas Department of Social and Rehabilitation Services Department on Aging Kansas Health Policy Authority State of Kansas Department of Social and Rehabilitation Services Department on Aging Kansas Health Policy Authority Notice of Proposed Nursing Facility Medicaid Rates for State Fiscal Year 2010; Methodology

More information

Emerging Issues in USMC Recruiting: Assessing the Success of Cat. IV Recruits in the Marine Corps

Emerging Issues in USMC Recruiting: Assessing the Success of Cat. IV Recruits in the Marine Corps CAB D0014741.A1/Final August 2006 Emerging Issues in USMC Recruiting: Assessing the Success of Cat. IV Recruits in the Marine Corps Dana L. Brookshire Anita U. Hattiangadi Catherine M. Hiatt 4825 Mark

More information

For More Information

For More Information CHILDREN AND FAMILIES EDUCATION AND THE ARTS ENERGY AND ENVIRONMENT HEALTH AND HEALTH CARE INFRASTRUCTURE AND TRANSPORTATION INTERNATIONAL AFFAIRS LAW AND BUSINESS NATIONAL SECURITY POPULATION AND AGING

More information

Prepared for North Gunther Hospital Medicare ID August 06, 2012

Prepared for North Gunther Hospital Medicare ID August 06, 2012 Prepared for North Gunther Hospital Medicare ID 000001 August 06, 2012 TABLE OF CONTENTS Introduction: Benchmarking Your Hospital 3 Section 1: Hospital Operating Costs 5 Section 2: Margins 10 Section 3:

More information

The "Misnorming" of the U.S. Military s Entrance Examination and Its Effect on Minority Enlistments

The Misnorming of the U.S. Military s Entrance Examination and Its Effect on Minority Enlistments Institute for Research on Poverty Discussion Paper no. 1017-93 The "Misnorming" of the U.S. Military s Entrance Examination and Its Effect on Minority Enlistments Joshua D. Angrist Department of Economics

More information

Measuring the relationship between ICT use and income inequality in Chile

Measuring the relationship between ICT use and income inequality in Chile Measuring the relationship between ICT use and income inequality in Chile By Carolina Flores c.a.flores@mail.utexas.edu University of Texas Inequality Project Working Paper 26 October 26, 2003. Abstract:

More information

Recruiting and Retention: An Overview of FY2010 and FY2011 Results for Active and Reserve Component Enlisted Personnel

Recruiting and Retention: An Overview of FY2010 and FY2011 Results for Active and Reserve Component Enlisted Personnel Recruiting and Retention: An Overview of and Results for Active and Reserve Component Enlisted Personnel Lawrence Kapp Specialist in Military Manpower Policy March 30, 2012 CRS Report for Congress Prepared

More information

THE ROLE OF HOSPITAL HETEROGENEITY IN MEASURING MARGINAL RETURNS TO MEDICAL CARE: A REPLY TO BARRECA, GULDI, LINDO, AND WADDELL

THE ROLE OF HOSPITAL HETEROGENEITY IN MEASURING MARGINAL RETURNS TO MEDICAL CARE: A REPLY TO BARRECA, GULDI, LINDO, AND WADDELL THE ROLE OF HOSPITAL HETEROGENEITY IN MEASURING MARGINAL RETURNS TO MEDICAL CARE: A REPLY TO BARRECA, GULDI, LINDO, AND WADDELL DOUGLAS ALMOND JOSEPH J. DOYLE, JR. AMANDA E. KOWALSKI HEIDI WILLIAMS In

More information

Michigan's Economic Development Policies

Michigan's Economic Development Policies Testimonies Upjohn Research home page 2003 Michigan's Economic Development Policies Timothy J. Bartik W.E. Upjohn Institute, bartik@upjohn.org George A. Erickcek W.E. Upjohn Institute, erickcek@upjohn.org

More information

The History and Evolution of Conscription in the U.S.

The History and Evolution of Conscription in the U.S. The History and Evolution of Conscription in the U.S. by Timothy Perri* This Draft: July 10, 2012 *Department of Economics, Appalachian State University, Boone, NC, 28608. perritj@gmail.com. The first

More information

Application of a uniform price quality adjusted discount auction for assigning voluntary separation pay

Application of a uniform price quality adjusted discount auction for assigning voluntary separation pay Calhoun: The NPS Institutional Archive Theses and Dissertations Thesis Collection 2011-03 Application of a uniform price quality adjusted discount auction for assigning voluntary separation pay Pearson,

More information

Economic Benefits of Less Restrictive Regulation of APRNs in North Carolina:

Economic Benefits of Less Restrictive Regulation of APRNs in North Carolina: Economic Benefits of Less Restrictive Regulation of APRNs in North Carolina: An Analysis of Local and Statewide Effects on Business Activity Christopher J. Conover, PhD Center for Health Policy and Inequalities

More information

Recruiting and Retention: An Overview of FY2006 and FY2007 Results for Active and Reserve Component Enlisted Personnel

Recruiting and Retention: An Overview of FY2006 and FY2007 Results for Active and Reserve Component Enlisted Personnel Order Code RL32965 Recruiting and Retention: An Overview of and Results for Active and Reserve Component Enlisted Personnel Updated February 7, 2008 Lawrence Kapp and Charles A. Henning Specialists in

More information

Capping Retired Pay for Senior Field Grade Officers

Capping Retired Pay for Senior Field Grade Officers Capping Retired Pay for Senior Field Grade Officers Force Management, Retention, and Cost Effects Beth J. Asch, Michael G. Mattock, James Hosek, Patricia K. Tong C O R P O R A T I O N For more information

More information

What Job Seekers Want:

What Job Seekers Want: Indeed Hiring Lab I March 2014 What Job Seekers Want: Occupation Satisfaction & Desirability Report While labor market analysis typically reports actual job movements, rarely does it directly anticipate

More information

Department of Defense INSTRUCTION. SUBJECT: Programming and Accounting for Active Military Manpower

Department of Defense INSTRUCTION. SUBJECT: Programming and Accounting for Active Military Manpower Department of Defense INSTRUCTION NUMBER 1120.11 April 9, 1981 SUBJECT: Programming and Accounting for Active Military Manpower ASD(MRA&L) References: (a) DoD Directive 5000.19, "Policies for the Management

More information

ARBITRATION DECISION October 16, 1985 CIN-4C-C Class Action. Between

ARBITRATION DECISION October 16, 1985 CIN-4C-C Class Action. Between ARBITRATION DECISION October 16, 1985 CIN-4C-C 33108 Class Action Between C' ~~ a 3 0 United States Postal Service and National Association of Letter Carriers Hopkins, Minnesota Branch 2942 ARBITRATOR

More information

Teleworking and Congestion: A Dynamic Bottleneck Analysis

Teleworking and Congestion: A Dynamic Bottleneck Analysis TI 2011-096/3 Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper Teleworking and Congestion: A Dynamic Bottleneck Analysis Sergejs Gubins Erik T. Verhoef Dept. of Spatial Economics, Faculty of Economics and Business

More information

2016 REPORT Community Care for the Elderly (CCE) Client Satisfaction Survey

2016 REPORT Community Care for the Elderly (CCE) Client Satisfaction Survey 2016 REPORT Community Care for the Elderly (CCE) Client Satisfaction Survey Program Services, Direct Service Workers, and Impact of Program on Lives of Clients i Florida Department of Elder Affairs, 2016

More information

Full-time Equivalents and Financial Costs Associated with Absenteeism, Overtime, and Involuntary Part-time Employment in the Nursing Profession

Full-time Equivalents and Financial Costs Associated with Absenteeism, Overtime, and Involuntary Part-time Employment in the Nursing Profession Full-time Equivalents and Financial Costs Associated with Absenteeism, Overtime, and Involuntary Part-time Employment in the Nursing Profession A Report prepared for the Canadian Nursing Advisory Committee

More information

HEALTH WORKFORCE SUPPLY AND REQUIREMENTS PROJECTION MODELS. World Health Organization Div. of Health Systems 1211 Geneva 27, Switzerland

HEALTH WORKFORCE SUPPLY AND REQUIREMENTS PROJECTION MODELS. World Health Organization Div. of Health Systems 1211 Geneva 27, Switzerland HEALTH WORKFORCE SUPPLY AND REQUIREMENTS PROJECTION MODELS World Health Organization Div. of Health Systems 1211 Geneva 27, Switzerland The World Health Organization has long given priority to the careful

More information

Forecasts of the Registered Nurse Workforce in California. June 7, 2005

Forecasts of the Registered Nurse Workforce in California. June 7, 2005 Forecasts of the Registered Nurse Workforce in California June 7, 2005 Conducted for the California Board of Registered Nursing Joanne Spetz, PhD Wendy Dyer, MS Center for California Health Workforce Studies

More information

GAO. DEPOT MAINTENANCE The Navy s Decision to Stop F/A-18 Repairs at Ogden Air Logistics Center

GAO. DEPOT MAINTENANCE The Navy s Decision to Stop F/A-18 Repairs at Ogden Air Logistics Center GAO United States General Accounting Office Report to the Honorable James V. Hansen, House of Representatives December 1995 DEPOT MAINTENANCE The Navy s Decision to Stop F/A-18 Repairs at Ogden Air Logistics

More information

Effect of the Variable Reenlistment Bonus on Reenlistment Rates: Empirical Results for FY 1971

Effect of the Variable Reenlistment Bonus on Reenlistment Rates: Empirical Results for FY 1971 ARPA ORDER NO.: 189-1 5020 Human Resources Research Office R-1502-ARPA June 1975 Effect of the Variable Reenlistment Bonus on Reenlistment Rates: Empirical Results for FY 1971 John H. Enns A Report prepared

More information

The social welfare losses of conscription: an evaluation for the 1980s.

The social welfare losses of conscription: an evaluation for the 1980s. Calhoun: The NPS Institutional Archive DSpace Repository Theses and Dissertations Thesis and Dissertation Collection 1986 The social welfare losses of conscription: an evaluation for the 1980s. Crouch,

More information

Final Report No. 101 April Trends in Skilled Nursing Facility and Swing Bed Use in Rural Areas Following the Medicare Modernization Act of 2003

Final Report No. 101 April Trends in Skilled Nursing Facility and Swing Bed Use in Rural Areas Following the Medicare Modernization Act of 2003 Final Report No. 101 April 2011 Trends in Skilled Nursing Facility and Swing Bed Use in Rural Areas Following the Medicare Modernization Act of 2003 The North Carolina Rural Health Research & Policy Analysis

More information

Report to the Congressional Committees. Consolidation of the Disability Evaluation System

Report to the Congressional Committees. Consolidation of the Disability Evaluation System Report to the Congressional Committees Consolidation of the Disability Evaluation System In response to: House Committee Report 112-78, to accompany H.R. 1540, the National Defense Authorization Act for

More information

Guidelines for the Virginia Investment Partnership Grant Program

Guidelines for the Virginia Investment Partnership Grant Program Guidelines for the Virginia Investment Partnership Grant Program Purpose: The Virginia Investment Partnership Grant Program ( VIP ) is used to encourage existing Virginia manufacturers or research and

More information

An Assessment of Recent Proposals to Improve the Montgomery G.I. Bill

An Assessment of Recent Proposals to Improve the Montgomery G.I. Bill D O C U M E N T E D B R I E F I N G R An Assessment of Recent Proposals to Improve the Montgomery G.I. Bill Beth J. Asch, C. Christine Fair, M. Rebecca Kilburn Prepared for the Office of the Secretary

More information

PALO ALTO ACCOUNTABLE AND AFFORDABLE HEALTH CARE INITIATIVE

PALO ALTO ACCOUNTABLE AND AFFORDABLE HEALTH CARE INITIATIVE PALO ALTO ACCOUNTABLE AND AFFORDABLE HEALTH CARE INITIATIVE SECTION 1. Chapter 5.40 is added to Title 5 of the Palo Alto Municipal Code, governing Health and Sanitation, to read: Sec. 5.40.010 Purpose

More information

Health Economics Program

Health Economics Program Health Economics Program Issue Paper July 2000 Home Care Provider Trends in Minnesota: 1994-1999 Background Minnesota has an interesting history with regard to home care trends. Although Medicare beneficiaries

More information

Attrition Rates and Performance of ChalleNGe Participants Over Time

Attrition Rates and Performance of ChalleNGe Participants Over Time CRM D0013758.A2/Final April 2006 Attrition Rates and Performance of ChalleNGe Participants Over Time Jennie W. Wenger Cathleen M. McHugh with Lynda G. Houck 4825 Mark Center Drive Alexandria, Virginia

More information

Job Search Behavior among the Employed and Non Employed

Job Search Behavior among the Employed and Non Employed Job Search Behavior among the Employed and Non Employed July 2015 R. Jason Faberman, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Andreas I. Mueller, Columbia University, NBER and IZA Ayşegül Şahin, Federal Reserve

More information

Results of the Clatsop County Economic Development Survey

Results of the Clatsop County Economic Development Survey Results of the Clatsop County Economic Development Survey Final Report for: Prepared for: Clatsop County Prepared by: Community Planning Workshop Community Service Center 1209 University of Oregon Eugene,

More information

EFFECTIVE ROOT CAUSE ANALYSIS AND CORRECTIVE ACTION PROCESS

EFFECTIVE ROOT CAUSE ANALYSIS AND CORRECTIVE ACTION PROCESS I International Symposium Engineering Management And Competitiveness 2011 (EMC2011) June 24-25, 2011, Zrenjanin, Serbia EFFECTIVE ROOT CAUSE ANALYSIS AND CORRECTIVE ACTION PROCESS Branislav Tomić * Senior

More information

JUN A1. UNCLASSIFIED GAO/PLRD-Al 40

JUN A1. UNCLASSIFIED GAO/PLRD-Al 40 A-102 647 GENERAL ACCOUNTING OFFICE WASHINGTON DC PROCUREMENT -- ETC F/G 15/5 V. HOUSEHOLD GOODS SHIPMENTS IN EXCESS OF MILITART SERVICEMEMBERS'-ETC(Ul JUN A1 UNCLASSIFIED GAO/PLRD-Al 40 N UNITED STATES

More information

Fertility Response to the Tax Treatment of Children

Fertility Response to the Tax Treatment of Children Fertility Response to the Tax Treatment of Children Kevin J. Mumford Purdue University Paul Thomas Purdue University April 2016 Abstract This paper uses variation in the child tax subsidy implicit in US

More information

CLIENT ALERT. Labor & Employment. National Labor Relations Board Rules That Charge Nurses May Be Supervisors. October 5, 2006

CLIENT ALERT. Labor & Employment. National Labor Relations Board Rules That Charge Nurses May Be Supervisors. October 5, 2006 Labor & Employment CLIENT ALERT October 5, 2006 National Labor Relations Board Rules That Charge Nurses May Be Supervisors Last Friday, the National Labor Relations Board issued its long-awaited decision

More information

For More Information

For More Information CHILDREN AND ADOLESCENTS CIVIL JUSTICE EDUCATION ENERGY AND ENVIRONMENT HEALTH AND HEALTH CARE This PDF document was made available from www.rand.org as a public service of the RAND Corporation. Jump down

More information

Population Representation in the Military Services: Fiscal Year 2011 Summary Report

Population Representation in the Military Services: Fiscal Year 2011 Summary Report Population Representation in the Military Services: Fiscal Year 2011 Summary Report 1 Introduction This is the 39 th annual Department of Defense (DoD) report describing characteristics of U.S. military

More information

Department of Defense INSTRUCTION

Department of Defense INSTRUCTION Department of Defense INSTRUCTION NUMBER 1304.31 March 12, 2013 USD(P&R) SUBJECT: Enlisted Bonus Program (EBP) References: See Enclosure 1 1. PURPOSE. In accordance with the authority in DoD Directive

More information

Military Recruiting Outlook

Military Recruiting Outlook Military Recruiting Outlook Recent Trends in Enlistment Propensity and Conversion of Potential Enlisted Supply Bruce R. Orvis Narayan Sastry Laurie L. McDonald Prepared for the United States Army Office

More information

The Economic Impact of North Dakota's Health Care Industry on the State's Economy in 1991

The Economic Impact of North Dakota's Health Care Industry on the State's Economy in 1991 April 1993 Agricultural Economics Report No. 296 o r%0%a.. -. - The Economic Impact of North Dakota's Health Care Industry on the State's Economy in 1991 Rita R. Hamm, JoAnn M. Thompson, Randal C. Coon,

More information

EXTENDING THE ANALYSIS TO TDY COURSES

EXTENDING THE ANALYSIS TO TDY COURSES Chapter Four EXTENDING THE ANALYSIS TO TDY COURSES So far the analysis has focused only on courses now being done in PCS mode, and it found that partial DL conversions of these courses enhances stability

More information

T he National Health Service (NHS) introduced the first

T he National Health Service (NHS) introduced the first 265 ORIGINAL ARTICLE The impact of co-located NHS walk-in centres on emergency departments Chris Salisbury, Sandra Hollinghurst, Alan Montgomery, Matthew Cooke, James Munro, Deborah Sharp, Melanie Chalder...

More information

GAO MILITARY PERSONNEL

GAO MILITARY PERSONNEL GAO United States Government Accountability Office Report to Congressional Committees June 2007 MILITARY PERSONNEL DOD Needs to Establish a Strategy and Improve Transparency over Reserve and National Guard

More information

GAO MILITARY BASE CLOSURES. DOD's Updated Net Savings Estimate Remains Substantial. Report to the Honorable Vic Snyder House of Representatives

GAO MILITARY BASE CLOSURES. DOD's Updated Net Savings Estimate Remains Substantial. Report to the Honorable Vic Snyder House of Representatives GAO United States General Accounting Office Report to the Honorable Vic Snyder House of Representatives July 2001 MILITARY BASE CLOSURES DOD's Updated Net Savings Estimate Remains Substantial GAO-01-971

More information

Military Retention Incentives: Evidence from the Air Force Selective Reenlistment Bonus

Military Retention Incentives: Evidence from the Air Force Selective Reenlistment Bonus Upjohn Institute Working Papers Upjohn Research home page 2015 Military Retention Incentives: Evidence from the Air Force Selective Reenlistment Bonus Justin Joffrion U.S. Air Force Academy Nathan Wozny

More information

INTERVIEW PLAN #2 STRUCTURED INTERVIEW ARMY PRECOMMISSIONING SELECTION COLLEGE BACKGROUND AND/OR MILITARY SERVICE

INTERVIEW PLAN #2 STRUCTURED INTERVIEW ARMY PRECOMMISSIONING SELECTION COLLEGE BACKGROUND AND/OR MILITARY SERVICE INTERVIEW PLAN #2 STRUCTURED INTERVIEW ARMY PRECOMMISSIONING SELECTION COLLEGE BACKGROUND AND/OR MILITARY SERVICE FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY - ONLY WHEN FILLED OUT Not to be shown to unauthorized persons Not

More information

Specifications for an Operational Two-Tiered Classification System for the Army Volume I: Report. Joseph Zeidner, Cecil Johnson, Yefim Vladimirsky,

Specifications for an Operational Two-Tiered Classification System for the Army Volume I: Report. Joseph Zeidner, Cecil Johnson, Yefim Vladimirsky, Technical Report 1108 Specifications for an Operational Two-Tiered Classification System for the Army Volume I: Report Joseph Zeidner, Cecil Johnson, Yefim Vladimirsky, and Susan Weldon The George Washington

More information

Improving Reenlistment Incentives and Processes

Improving Reenlistment Incentives and Processes CRM D0015254.A2/Final January 2007 Improving Reenlistment Incentives and Processes Martha E. Koopman 4825 Mark Center Drive Alexandria, Virginia 22311-1850 Approved for distribution: January 2007 Henry

More information

Department of Defense INSTRUCTION. Continuation of Commissioned Officers on Active Duty and on the Reserve Active Status List

Department of Defense INSTRUCTION. Continuation of Commissioned Officers on Active Duty and on the Reserve Active Status List Department of Defense INSTRUCTION NUMBER 1320.08 March 14, 2007 USD(P&R) SUBJECT: Continuation of Commissioned Officers on Active Duty and on the Reserve Active Status List References: (a) DoD Directive

More information

REPLACING MILITARY PERSONNEL IN SUPPORT POSITIONS WITH CIVILIAN EMPLOYEES DECEMBER What Costs of Replacing Military Support Personnel With Civi

REPLACING MILITARY PERSONNEL IN SUPPORT POSITIONS WITH CIVILIAN EMPLOYEES DECEMBER What Costs of Replacing Military Support Personnel With Civi DECEMBER 2015 Replacing Military Personnel in Support Positions With Civilian Employees Provided as a convenience, this screen-friendly version is identical in content to the principal ( printer-friendly

More information

R&D Tax Incentives. Pierre Mohnen

R&D Tax Incentives. Pierre Mohnen / ' d W E dd R&D Tax Incentives Pierre Mohnen Main findings: Level-based R&D tax credits are subject to a serious deadweight loss. Increment-based R&D tax credits are not subject to that deadweight loss,

More information

Officer Overexecution: Analysis and Solutions

Officer Overexecution: Analysis and Solutions Officer Overexecution: Analysis and Solutions Ann D. Parcell August 2015 Distribution unlimited CNA s annotated briefings are either condensed presentations of the results of formal CNA studies that have

More information

Policy Rules for the ORIO Grant Facility

Policy Rules for the ORIO Grant Facility Policy Rules for the ORIO Grant Facility Policy Rules grant facility ORIO 2012 1. What is ORIO?... 3 2. Definitions... 3 3. The role of infrastructure... 4 4. Implementation... 5 5. Target group... 5 6.

More information

Ordinary Residence and Continuity of Care Policy

Ordinary Residence and Continuity of Care Policy COMMUNITY WELLBEING AND SOCIAL CARE DIRECTORATE Director of Adult Social Services Isle of Wight Council Adult Social Care Ordinary Residence and Continuity of Care Policy August 2016 1 Document Information

More information

How Does Sea Duty Affect First-Term Reenlistment?: An Analysis Using Post-9/11 Data

How Does Sea Duty Affect First-Term Reenlistment?: An Analysis Using Post-9/11 Data CRM D0013608.A2/Final May 2006 How Does Sea Duty Affect First-Term Reenlistment?: An Analysis Using Post-9/11 Data Diana S. Lien Cathleen M. McHugh with David Gregory 4825 Mark Center Drive Alexandria,

More information

Non-Prior Service Reserve Enlistments. Supply Estimates and Forecasts. Hong W. Tan RAND NATIONAL DEFENSE RESEARCH INSTITUTE

Non-Prior Service Reserve Enlistments. Supply Estimates and Forecasts. Hong W. Tan RAND NATIONAL DEFENSE RESEARCH INSTITUTE Non-Prior Service Reserve Enlistments Supply Estimates and Forecasts Hong W. Tan 19960904 022 DTIC QUAidT* ijmbf ACTED 1 RAND NATIONAL DEFENSE RESEARCH INSTITUTE The research described in this report was

More information

Hospital financing in France: Introducing casemix-based payment

Hospital financing in France: Introducing casemix-based payment Hospital financing in France: Introducing casemix-based payment Xavière Michelot Chargée de Mission - Mission Tarification à l Activité xaviere.michelot@sante.gouv.fr Agenda 1. The current French hospital

More information

Participant Satisfaction Survey Summary Report Fiscal Year 2012

Participant Satisfaction Survey Summary Report Fiscal Year 2012 Participant Satisfaction Survey Summary Report Fiscal Year 2012 Prepared by: SPEC Associates Detroit, Michigan www.specassociates.org Introduction Since 2003, Area Agency on Aging 1-B (AAA 1-B) 1 has been

More information

Guidelines for the Major Eligible Employer Grant Program

Guidelines for the Major Eligible Employer Grant Program Guidelines for the Major Eligible Employer Grant Program Purpose: The Major Eligible Employer Grant Program ( MEE ) is used to encourage major basic employers to invest in Virginia and to provide a significant

More information

Growing microenterprises: How gender and family can impact outcomes evidence from Uganda. What Works in SME Development. 1.

Growing microenterprises: How gender and family can impact outcomes evidence from Uganda. What Works in SME Development. 1. Issue Brief No 2, March 2017 Growing microenterprises: How gender and family can impact outcomes evidence from Uganda 1. Key findings Lack of access to finance and management ability are important constraints

More information

U.S. Hiring Trends Q3 2015:

U.S. Hiring Trends Q3 2015: U.S. Hiring Trends Q3 2015: icims Quarterly Report on Employer & Job Seeker Behaviors 2017 icims Inc. All Rights Reserved. Table of Contents The following report presents job creation and talent supply

More information

How to deal with Emergency at the Operating Room

How to deal with Emergency at the Operating Room How to deal with Emergency at the Operating Room Research Paper Business Analytics Author: Freerk Alons Supervisor: Dr. R. Bekker VU University Amsterdam Faculty of Science Master Business Mathematics

More information