NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOME CARE REIMBURSEMENT, LONG-TERM CARE UTILIZATION, AND HEALTH OUTCOMES. Robin McKnight

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOME CARE REIMBURSEMENT, LONG-TERM CARE UTILIZATION, AND HEALTH OUTCOMES. Robin McKnight"

Transcription

1 NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOME CARE REIMBURSEMENT, ONG-TERM CARE UTIIZATION, AND HEATH OUTCOMES Robin McKnight Working Paper NATIONA BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA April 2004 I am grateful for the guidance of Jon Gruber, Jim Poterba and David Autor and for helpful discussions with Daron Acemoglu, Emek Basker, Tom Davidoff, Peter Diamond, Amy Finkelstein, Chris Hansen, Patricia Keenan, Cindy Perry, Jon Reuter, arry Singell, Wes Wilson and seminar participants at Amherst College, CBO, UC-Davis, the Federal Reserve Board, Harvard School of Public Health, MIT, RAND, Texas A&M s Bush School, and the University of Oregon. Funding from the National Institute on Aging, through Grant #K12-AG00983 to the National Bureau of Economic Research, is gratefully acknowledged.the views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research by Robin McKnight. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including notice, is given to the source.

2 Home Care Reimbursement, ong-term Care Utilization, and Health Outcomes Robin McKnight NBER Working Paper No April 2004 JE No. I1 ABSTRACT ong-term care currently comprises almost 10% of national health expenditures and is projected to rise rapidly over coming decades. A key, and relatively poorly understood, element of long-term care is home health care. I use a substantial change in Medicare reimbursement policy, which took the form of tightly binding average per-patient reimbursement caps, to address several questions about the market for home care. I find that the reimbursement change was associated with a large drop in the provision of home care. This drop was concentrated among unhealthy beneficiaries, which is consistent with the incentives for patient selection inherent in the per-patient caps. I find that the decline in home health utilization was not offset by increases in institutional long-term care or other medical care and that there were no associated adverse health consequences. However, approximately one-quarter of the decline in Medicare spending was offset by increases in out-ofpocket expenditures for home health care, with the offset concentrated in higher income populations. Despite the value of home health care implied by the out-of-pocket expenditures, I find that the welfare implications of the reimbursement change were ambiguous. Robin McKnight Economics, 435 PC 1285 University of Oregon Eugene, OR and NBER robinm@uoregon.edu

3 I. Introduction ong-term care is a policy issue of growing importance in the United States. In 2000, combined home- and community-based care and nursing home costs for the elderly totaled $98 billion, with Medicare and Medicaid bearing 56% of these costs (U.S. Congress 2000). This spending level corresponds to roughly 10% of national health expenditures and 1% of GDP. Moreover, demand for long-term care is expected to increase dramatically over the coming decades due to the aging of the population. Estimates suggest that the number of elderly people requiring assistance with activities of daily living will increase by 42% between 2000 and 2020 (U.S. Congress 2000). Many of these elderly people will require long-term care, in the form of nursing home care or home health care. Traditionally, long-term care was synonymous with institutional care at nursing homes. In 1980, expenditures for institutional care were seven times greater than expenditures for home health care (HHS 2002). But the past two decades have seen a radical shift in the composition of long-term care spending. Nursing home usage has fallen substantially; between 1985 and 1995, there was an 8.2% decline in the share of elderly who reported staying overnight in a nursing facility on a given day (Bishop 1999). And there has been a parallel substantial rise in long-term care delivered in the home setting, home health care, over the same period, with an 82% increase in the share of Medicare beneficiaries who used home care and a 208% increase in the number of home care visits per user (U.S. Congress 2000). As a result, by 1995, expenditures for nursing home care were only twice as great as expenditures for home care (HHS 2002). This dramatic shift in the composition of spending on long-term care naturally leads to several important questions. First, was the increased use of home health care during this period causally related to the reduction in nursing home use? Second, given the lower costs associated 1

4 with providing home care, did the increased use of home health care reduce overall expenditures on long-term care? Finally, what was the impact of increased home care utilization on the health status of the elderly? This paper addresses these questions using evidence from a policy change that caused a dramatic reversal of home care utilization growth rates. Specifically, I examine the short-run impact of a substantial change to Medicare reimbursement for home care in October The policy change had dramatic aggregate effects, causing an immediate 30% decline in Medicare expenditures for home care. The reimbursement change, which involved the imposition of average per-patient reimbursement caps, also fundamentally changed the incentives faced by home care agencies. By shifting from fee-for-service to a more prospective reimbursement system, Medicare s home care program encountered a trade-off between incentives for patient selection and incentives for efficiency in the production of medical care (Newhouse (1996)). In this paper, I model a profitmaximizing home health agency with two patient types -- long-term and short-term. The model shows that the imposition of an average per-patient cap on Medicare reimbursement can lead the agency to intentionally shift the composition of its patients towards short-term patients and to provide a lower intensity of care to its long-term patients. The empirical analysis uses data from the Medicare Current Beneficiary Survey (MCBS) to examine whether the imposition of average per-patient caps shifted the composition of home care utilization and affected health status and use of other types of care. To identify effects of the reimbursement change, I utilize state variation in the restrictiveness of the per-patient caps. In particular, caps were constructed as a weighted average of the historical costs per home care user in each agency and the mean historical costs per home care user in each 2

5 agency s Census division. In consequence, agencies with otherwise similar utilization patterns faced differential incentives across states to cut back on per-patient costs after the Medicare reimbursement policy change. For example, aggregate data suggests that agencies in Georgia and Oklahoma provided similar average amounts of care to their users in the pre-policy years, but agencies in Georgia faced more stringent per-patient caps than those in Oklahoma, due to the regional component of the per-patient cap calculation. Using this identification strategy, I find significant declines in the utilization of home health care in the post-policy period, consistent with aggregate data. Strikingly, I find that these declines were driven exclusively by declines in use among the beneficiaries who appeared likely to incur the highest home care costs. Relatively healthy beneficiaries experienced an insignificant increase in home care usage, whereas relatively unhealthy beneficiaries experienced a significant decline. These findings are consistent with the model s prediction that agencies would respond to the reimbursement change by favoring relatively healthy, low-cost patients. A subsequent analysis examines how changes in the cap and the consequent use of home health care affected utilization of other types of care, providing evidence on the substitutability of home care for nursing home and other types of care. I find no evidence that the policyinduced reduction in home health care increased the likelihood of receiving long-term facility care. I also find little evidence of increased expenditures for other types of care, although my estimates are somewhat imprecise. Moreover, I find no evidence that this reduction in home health care utilization had an adverse impact on the health of the elderly. One possible explanation for these findings is that individuals offset the cuts in financing for public home health care visits by increasing their own out-of-pocket spending on home health 3

6 care. I find evidence that roughly 22% of the decline in Medicare home health care spending was offset by increased out-of-pocket spending. Increases in out-of-pocket spending were concentrated among relatively high-income beneficiaries but, even among those low-income beneficiaries who did not offset the cuts, there was no offsetting increase in other health care spending and no adverse impact on health. Finally, the fact that individuals desired to offset some of these public spending cuts suggests that they were partially valued on the margin. I therefore discuss the welfare consequences of this policy change, but conclude that the net effect on welfare was ambiguous. II. Background Home health care is medical care that is provided in the home of the patient. To qualify for Medicare coverage of home health care, a beneficiary must be home-bound, under the care of a physician and require part-time or intermittent skilled care. The early 1990s witnessed unprecedented growth in Medicare expenditures for home health care, with expenditures increasing from $3.4 billion in 1989 to $19.2 billion in During this time, the percentage of beneficiaries who used home care almost doubled from 5.1% to 9.5% and the number of visits per user almost tripled from 27 to 79 (U.S. Congress 2000). This growth was precipitated by a liberalization of the Medicare home care benefit rules, following the settlement of a class action lawsuit in Newhouse (2002) argues that this growth also reflects increased use of post-acute care as a substitute for the last days of a hospital stay, in response to Medicare s prospective payment system (PPS) for hospital care. In response to rapidly rising expenditures, Congress mandated the development of a PPS for home care in the Balanced Budget Act of 1997 (BBA 97). In order to slow the growth of 1 Dollar amounts, throughout the paper, are in real (1999) dollars 4

7 home health expenditures in the interim before the PPS was ready to be implemented, BBA 97 also created an Interim Payment System (IPS) that took effect in October At the same time, Congress mandated PPS for Medicare reimbursement of other forms of post-acute care, including short-term skilled nursing facilities (SNFs) and rehabilitation services, but the IPS was the first policy to take effect. Prior to BBA 97, home care agencies were reimbursed for their reasonable costs, subject to a per-visit cap. The per-visit cap, which was equal to 112% of the national average cost for each type of visit, was applied to aggregate agency payments. This reimbursement policy was considered inadequate, because agencies had no incentive to minimize the number of visits provided to each patient. Furthermore, there were no financial constraints on demand, because beneficiaries face no cost-sharing for home care. Beginning in October 1997, the IPS added an additional limit to the calculation of agency reimbursements: an annual per-patient cap. This new, agency-specific cap was calculated as a weighted average of each agency s 1994 average per-patient costs and the 1994 regional average per-patient costs. The agency s own average per-patient costs comprised 75% of the cap, with the regional average per-patient costs comprising the remaining 25%. 2 Thus, those agencies that had above-average per-patient costs within their region in 1994 received per-patient caps that were lower than their 1994 per-patient costs; agencies that had below-average per-patient costs in 1994 received caps that were higher than their 1994 per-patient costs. In a regulatory impact statement in March 1998, HCFA projected that 58% of agencies would exceed the per-patient cap; by the following year, this projection was raised to 79% (Federal Register 1998, 1999). 2 New agencies, for whom 1994 reimbursement information was not available, received a cap equal to the national median cap, adjusted for regional differences in labor costs. In response to complaints that this formula led to new agencies in some areas receiving more generous caps than old agencies, 1999 caps for old agencies with caps below the national median were increased. The increase was equal to one-third of the difference between the agency s baseline cap and the cap for new agencies. 5

8 Newhouse (1996) shows that prospective reimbursement, such as the IPS, yields two distinct incentives for health care providers: (1) a production efficiency incentive arising from the fact that providers can keep any residual reimbursement; and (2) a selection incentive arising from the fact that lump-sum payment transfers the risk of high costs to the provider. Newhouse reviews the empirical evidence on this issue, which generally supports the theoretical prediction that providers and insurers respond to capitated payments by selecting the healthiest patients. It follows that full prospectivity is unlikely to be optimal, due to the welfare loss from increased patient selection. Empirical evidence about the response of home health agencies to a transition from feefor-service to prospective reimbursement is available from an experiment in the early 1990s. Cheh (2001) evaluates the impact of the experimental PPS on patient selection, health care utilization and health outcomes. She finds strong evidence of declines in home care utilization, but little evidence of patient selection, adverse health effects, or increased utilization of other forms of care. However, there are several reasons that these conclusions may not generalize to the situation of BBA 97. First, important features of the experimental PPS notably, the use of adjustments for agency case-mix were not used in the IPS. Second, agencies participated voluntarily in the experiment and were insured against 97-99% of any losses that were generated as a result of the experimental PPS. In contrast, the IPS was mandatory and did not offer any insurance against agency losses. As a result, agencies may have reacted more strongly to the IPS than they did to the experimental PPS. In January 1998, CBO projected that BBA 97 would lead to a slowing of the growth rate of Medicare s home care expenditures (CBO 1997). However, as Figure 1 shows, home health expenditures actually plummeted by almost $6 billion in Figures 2 and 3 show that both 6

9 the dramatic pre-1997 increase in expenditures and the striking post-1997 decline in expenditures were driven primarily by changes in the number of visits per beneficiary, rather than changes in costs per visit. Data from the Health Care Financing Review s annual statistical supplement indicate that the striking decline in visits per beneficiary reflects substantial decreases in both the share of beneficiaries who used home care (an 11% decline between 1996 and 1998) and in the number of visits per user (a 31% decline between 1996 and 1998). Some observers have complained that declines in home care led to increases in the utilization of other forms of health care. 3 Indeed, it is plausible that Medicare could lose money by cutting back on home care reimbursement if, for example, the policy change led patients to substitute relatively expensive inpatient care for less expensive home care. Alternatively, Medicaid or individual patients could bear financial costs if patients moved from home care to nursing homes. The issue of substitution between home care and other forms of care has long been a question of interest to health economists. In the early 1980s, the National ong Term Care Demonstration project was implemented, providing case management and community services to a treatment group. Kemper (1988) summarizes the conclusions of the evaluation. He reports that patients and informal care-givers in the treatment group were more satisfied with the care and quality of life; however, the additional services led to higher net costs because there were no offsetting decreases in the costs of other care, notably nursing home care. The findings of other, smaller demonstrations have suggested that there may be some opportunities for home care to 3 For instance, a hospital administrator told the New York Times, Our hospital has been busier since the cutbacks in home health care. We attribute quite a bit of that to the fact that we can t provide adequate home care. Patients are admitted or readmitted to the hospital or to a nursing home, and both of those are more expensive than home care (Pear 2000). 7

10 substitute for other care, especially if increases in home care usage are well-targeted. 4 However, in the 20 years since these experiments, many aspects of the health care system such as hospital reimbursement have changed in ways that are likely to have impacted home care utilization patterns. This paper provides updated evidence that is more relevant in the current health care environment. Hadley et al. (2000) consider the relationship between post-acute Medicare home health care and health status in the early 1990s. They rely on year effects and regional market characteristics to identify the impact of home health care and find a positive effect. Their research, however, focuses only on a subset of home health users and is therefore not generalizable to the case of the IPS. III. Theoretical Framework The intention behind the IPS legislation was to provide an incentive for agencies to provide care efficiently. awmakers intended that payments on behalf of patients whose costs were lower than average would subsidize more costly patients; the balance of low and high cost patients would determine whether an agency would exceed its aggregate per beneficiary cap (U.S. Congress 2000). However, a simple model, evaluated under reasonable assumptions, suggests that the IPS also introduced an incentive for agencies to favor patients who appeared likely to incur low costs. 4 Hughes, Susan, arry Manheim, Perry Edelman, and Kendon Conrad (1987). Kemper (1988) cites additional evidence from Blackman, D. et al (1985). South Carolina Community ong Term Care Project: Report of Findings. Spartanburg: South Carolina State Health and Human Services Commission. 8

11 Pre-policy Suppose there are two types of patients, those with short-term needs, type S, and those with long-term needs, type. An agency chooses the number of short-term patients to treat, N S, and the number of long-term patients to treat, N, to maximize its profits. Under pre-policy reimbursement, the agency receives reimbursement, P, for each unit of care intensity provided to either type of patient. P is fixed at Medicare s per-visit cap for each visit. I initially assume that the level of care intensity, I i, is fixed for each type of patient. It is convenient to think of I i as the number of home health care visits for a patient of type i. The cost of providing a unit of care intensity is C. I assume that P is greater than C to insure agency solvency. The agency s profits are equal to the number of patients of each type that it chooses to treat, N i, multiplied by the perpatient profit for each type of patient: ( P I C ) i I i. The number of patients treated, N i, is constrained to be less than or equal to the number of patients who demand services from the agency, D i, which is initially assumed to be exogenously determined. The agrangian is: (1) = N ( P I C I ) + N ( P I C I ) µ ( N D ) γ ( N D ) S S S S S The first-order conditions show that, because PI i is assumed to be greater than CI i, the demand constraints must be binding. Agencies will treat as many patients of type i as are available, because the marginal profit from treating an additional patient is always positive. The following graph shows the price and cost curves for long-term patients. As the first-order conditions suggest, N is determined by D in this graph. The graph for short-term patients is comparable. 9

12 Dollars P*I C*I N =D ong-term patients Post-policy The policy change can be incorporated into this simple model by adding an average per-patient cap, X, to the pre-policy reimbursement formula. Under the cap, reimbursements are restricted to be no greater than X N S + N ). That is, an additional constraint is added to the profit maximization problem: ( (2) P N I + N I ) X ( N + N ) ( S S S For the purpose of the analysis, I assume that P I X C I and that the reimbursement S constraint is binding. It may seem counterintuitive that an agency would continue to treat long-term patients at all when X C I. However, an agency will continue to receive full pre-policy reimbursement for the marginal long-term patient ( P I ) so long as the agency s average reimbursement 10

13 remains below the per-patient cap ( X ). Average reimbursement will remain below the cap as long as the agency treats enough short-term patients, whose costs all fall below the cap. Agencies will maximize profit subject to the original demand constraints and subject to the new reimbursement constraint. The new agrangian is: (3) = N S λ µ ( P I S C I S ) + N ( P I C I ) P ( N S I S + N I ) X ( N S + N ) ( N D ) γ ( N D ) ( ) S S The new first-order conditions for profit maximization are therefore: d dn (4) = ( P I C I ) λ ( P I X ) µ = 0 and: S d dn S (5) = ( P I C I ) λ ( P I X ) γ = 0 S S Because of the assumption that P C > 0, we know that the first term of (4) is positive. Because of the assumption that P I S X, we know that the second term of (4) is also positive. Therefore, in order to set the first-order condition equal to zero, it must be the case that µ is also positive. This fact implies that the constraint, N D, is binding. In contrast, it is not S S necessarily true that the demand constraint for long-term patients, N D, is binding, because the first term of (5) is positive and the second term of (5) is negative. Moreover, if the perpatient cap is a binding constraint on reimbursement, it follows that there is a single value of N, * N, that maximizes agency profit. By the reimbursement constraint, it must be the case that: 11

14 (6) N * = D S ( X P I ( P I X ) S ) This equation implies that the agency will treat more long-term patients as the demand among short-term patients increases, because each additional short-term patient eases the reimbursement cap. The agency will treat more long-term patients as the difference between the cap and increases, because this difference also eases the cap. The agency will treat fewer long-term patients as the difference between the cap and P I S P I increases, because this difference increases the constraint imposed by the reimbursement cap. This equation highlights the link between the reimbursement that an agency receives for short-term patients and its ability to profitably treat any long-term patients. Reimbursement for short-term patients is always below the cap and, therefore, allows the agency to stay below the cap on average while collecting reimbursement above the cap for some long-term patients. The following graph illustrates this point by showing the marginal reimbursement and marginal cost curves for long-term patients, for a given level of short-term patient demand. 12

15 Dollars P*I C*I Per-patient cap N * D ong-term patients At points below * N, the agency receives full reimbursement, P I, for each long-term patient, because there are enough short-term patients that the per-patient cap is not a binding constraint. Because the marginal profit from an additional long-term patient is positive, the agency will meet all demand in this range. At points above * N, however, the agency receives only X, which is below the cost, for each long-term patient. Per-patient marginal profits are negative in this range, so the agency will choose to provide care to no more than * N patients. One element of this model that seems particularly unrealistic is the assumption that agencies cannot adjust I i, the number of visits that they provide to a particular type of beneficiary. Solving a more detailed model, which allows for some adjustment of I i and assumes that demand is an increasing function of I i, yields the same prediction as the simpler model, plus an additional prediction: agencies are more likely to decrease the intensity of care to long-term patients than to short-term patients. This new prediction reflects the fact that an increase in the intensity of care to short-term patients has the benefit of relaxing the demand constraint. 13

16 Increasing intensity of care to long-term patients is less beneficial to the agency, however, since demand is less likely to be a constraint. The insight provided by this model is that, under reasonable assumptions, agencies may attempt to increase the share of short-term patients in their caseload and may provide higher intensity of care to those patients in order to attract more of them. Agencies may also decrease the share of long-term patients and decrease the intensity of care provided to them. The differential impact of the average per-patient cap on the probability that long-term patients receive any care is an important prediction of the model and is tested in Section 6 of the paper. The prediction that the per-patient cap will differentially affect intensity of care for long-term patients, however, is not directly testable. IV. Data and Empirical Strategy I use data from the MCBS to consider agency responses to the IPS and related changes in beneficiary utilization of care and health status. The MCBS surveys a rotating panel of Medicare beneficiaries, with an over-sampling of older beneficiaries. It combines administrative data from Medicare claims with survey data from several interviews with beneficiaries (or proxies, for beneficiaries who cannot participate in an interview) over the course of a year. The resulting data set provides information on utilization and costs of medical care, in addition to information on demographics and health status. Utilization and costs are categorized based on the type of care and the setting; categories include long-term facility, short-term institutional, inpatient, 14

17 outpatient, medical provider, home health, hospice, and prescription drugs. 5 The key dependent variables in my analyses are annual expenditures for each type of care. The MCBS was conducted annually beginning in My data include 99,005 Medicare beneficiary observations from the surveys, including 14,597 observations that report some home health utilization during the year. 6 Of the home health users, 3,634 were in the post-policy period. Summary statistics are provided in Table 1. The first column shows statistics for the full sample. The second column provides summary statistics for observations that have relatively high predicted home care costs. Predicted costs were imputed based on each observation s characteristics and the coefficients from a regression of total home care costs on individual characteristics among those observations that had home health expenditures in the pre-policy period. The resulting predicted costs are a measure of the costs that each person was likely to have incurred if they had used home health care during the pre-policy period. The characteristics that were used to predict home care costs include age, gender, marital status, race, difficulties with walking, writing, lifting and stooping, as well as 18 diagnosis dummy variables. 7 Table 2 shows some of the coefficients on the characteristics that were used to impute predicted costs to the full sample. I define high cost beneficiaries as those individuals whose predicted costs are above $3,877, the 75 th percentile prediction for all Medicare beneficiaries in the sample. The summary statistics in Table 1 show that the group with relatively high predicted costs has higher utilization levels of all forms of medical care than the predicted low-cost beneficiaries, reflecting 5 Facility care and institutional care both refer to nursing home care; they are distinguished by the expected length of care. Medical provider events may refer to doctor visits, laboratory and surgical services, or purchases of medical equipment and supplies. 6 1,812 observations are excluded from the main analysis because of missing covariate values. 7 Eighteen diagnosis dummy variables indicate whether an individual has ever received a diagnosis of Alzheimer s disease, angina pectoris, arthritis, broken hip, cancer, diabetes, emphysema, hardening of the arteries, hypertension, mental retardation, mental disorders, myocardial infarction, osteoporosis, other heart conditions, paralysis, Parkinson s disease, stroke, and amputation of an arm or leg. 15

18 the relatively poor health of observations in the predicted high-cost group. In the empirical analysis, I test for differential impacts of the IPS on these two groups of beneficiaries. I exploit state-level variation in the restrictiveness of IPS per-patient caps to identify the effect of the caps on beneficiary utilization of care and health outcomes. The predictions of the model were for individual agencies but they should also hold, on average, at the state level. Variation in restrictiveness arises from the fact that the per-patient cap was based on both the agency s historical costs and the region s average historical costs. Thus, agencies that had above-average costs within their region were penalized by the regional component of the cap and faced more restrictive caps; agencies that had below-average costs within their region benefited from the regional component of the cap and faced less restrictive caps. For my empirical analysis, I create a measure of restrictiveness based on the 1994 state average visits per user, published in the Health Care Financing Review s annual statistical supplement. Restrictiveness technically depends on 1994 Medicare payments per user, but these payments as well as the IPS caps are adjusted across localities to reflect the differences in the costs of providing care. Thus, visits per user provide a measure of utilization that is more directly comparable across regions and yields a more accurate measure of actual restrictiveness than a measure using payment data. 8 From each state s average visits per user in 1994, I subtract the average visits per user in that state s Census division, the relevant region for calculating perpatient caps. 9 The resulting measure of restrictiveness ranges from -41 to +35 visits. In the analysis below, I use this measure, interacted with a dummy variable indicating the post-policy period, to identify the effects of the IPS. I define the post-policy period as the years 1998 and 8 When a payment-based measure of restrictiveness is used, instead of the preferred visits-based measure, the results of the analysis are qualitatively unchanged. 9 For 1999 data, I adjust the measure of restrictiveness to reflect increases in caps for those states that had average caps below the national median cap. 16

19 1999; the last 3 months of 1997 are technically part of the post-policy period but, because the data is annual, these months are included with pre-policy data in my analysis. 10 To graphically illustrate the basis for my identification strategy, I have classified states into high, medium and low restrictiveness states, based on the continuous measure of restrictiveness that is used in regressions. Figures 4 and 5 use aggregate data from the Health Care Financing Review s annual statistical supplement to show that states with relatively restrictive caps had pre-policy trends that were similar to states with relatively unrestrictive caps, but experienced substantially larger post-policy declines in home care usage. 11 States with relatively restrictive caps experienced a 32% decline in users per beneficiary and a 47% decline in visits per user between 1996 and In contrast, states with relatively unrestrictive caps experienced a 24% decline in users per beneficiary and a 37% decline in visits per user. The basic estimating equation takes the following form: (7) Y ist = α + γ Re strict + + s s 1 δ State s hs s δ State s s * Post * trend t t + t + X s ist φ State hs β + * trend * HighCost i s s φ State s * HighCost + ε ist s + i t + η Year t t ht t η Year * HighCost t i The coefficient of interest, γ 1, is on the interaction between the state-level measure of restrictiveness and the post-policy dummy variable; this coefficient is shown in the first row of each column in each of the tables that is discussed below. This coefficient measures the impact of living during the post-policy period in a state that provided an additional one visit per user above the regional average during the pre-policy period. I control separately for state and year fixed effects, state trends, as well as separate state and year fixed effects and state trends for 10 The qualitative results of the analysis are not sensitive to exclusion of the 1997 data. The magnitudes of the effects on home health care are, as expected, larger when 1997 is excluded. 11 Aggregate data for 1999 is from GAO (2000). 17

20 beneficiaries with high predicted costs, and individual characteristics and diagnoses. Coefficients for some of these control variables are shown in the lower rows of each table. The main regressions of interest in my analysis use continuous dependent variables. I estimate these equations using OS. For binary dependent variables, I report marginal effects from Probit estimation. The critical identifying assumption of the empirical strategy is that there are no differential trends in states that faced relatively high restrictiveness due to the IPS. For example, if there were mean reversion in home care utilization, states with high pre-policy usage would experience decreases in utilization in the post-policy period, even in the absence of any policy change. Because states that faced relatively high restrictiveness also had relatively high prepolicy utilization levels, there is a possibility that my measure of restrictiveness simply captures the mean reversion of high utilization states. It is important to note, first of all, that there is no evidence of mean reversion in the pre-policy period (as shown in Figures 4 and 5), so it is not clear why we should expect mean reversion in the post-policy period. Nevertheless, mean reversion is a concern and one of the ways that I address it is by using the fact that my measure of restrictiveness depends on a state s pre-policy utilization relative to other states in its region, not relative to the rest of the country. States that have similar pre-policy utilization may face the same degree of mean reversion, but would face different IPS restrictiveness depending on whether their utilization is higher or lower than other states in the division. 12 ikewise, states that have very similar measures of restrictiveness had very different utilization levels in For instance, in 1994, home health users in Oklahoma received an average of 106 visits and users in Georgia received a comparable 102 visits (Health Care Financing Review 1996). However, the IPS was substantially more restrictive for Georgia, because the average home health user in Georgia in 1994 received 33 more visits than the 18

21 In order to formally account for the possibility of mean reversion in my empirical analysis, I run my regressions both with and without a control for mean reversion. The mean reversion control variable is an interaction between the 1994 average visits per user in each state and a dummy variable for the post-policy period. This additional term accounts for the fact that states with high utilization in the pre-policy period may have decreased their utilization even in the absence of the IPS. As discussed below, the majority of my results are not sensitive to the inclusion of this additional term. This specification takes the following form: (8) Y ist = α + γ + + t t 1 Re strict s * Postt + γ 2 η Year + t ht t η Year * HighCost t s δ State s i s Visits94 * trend + s t hs + s s δ State * Post φ State s hs t * trend + X s t ist β + * HighCost * HighCost s φ State s i i + ε ist s V. Empirical Results A. Effect on Home Health Care Utilization The results for home care utilization in Table 3 confirm the evidence from aggregate data: beneficiaries in states that had above-regional-average visits per user in 1994 had larger declines in home health care utilization in the post-policy period. To interpret the magnitude of the coefficients, I calculate the implied impact on a typical state, which received a perbeneficiary cap that precluded reimbursement for 6.32 visits that the typical pre-policy user received. The assumption that the per-beneficiary cap would permit reimbursement for 6.32 average user in the region; the average user in Oklahoma, in contrast, received only 4 more visits than the average user in the region. 13 The restrictiveness measures for Kansas and Mississippi are 9 and 8, respectively, but users in Kansas in 1994 received an average of 56 visits, whereas users in Mississippi received an average of 114 visits (Health Care Financing Review 1996). 19

22 fewer visits per user in a typical state is based on pre-policy utilization levels and HCFA s 1999 estimates of how tightly the caps constrained agency reimbursement. 14 The first column of Table 3 shows results for a regression that controls only for state and year fixed effects and implies a decline of 3.4 visits per beneficiary in the typical state. The second column illustrates that the results are robust to inclusion of individual-level covariates, implying a decline of 3.3 visits per beneficiary in the typical state. The third column, which corresponds to the basic estimating equation specified in Equation 7, adds controls for state-level trends. The coefficient implies a decline of 4.9 visits per beneficiary in the typical state. Finally, the fourth column adds the interaction between 1994 state average visits per user and a postpolicy dummy variable. In this specification, the implied impact of the IPS is a decrease of 2.8 visits. In fact, average visits per beneficiary fell by 4.6 between 1996 and 1999, so each of these regressions suggests an impact of the IPS that is consistent with the aggregate data. These regression results show the impact on average utilization of home health care. In Figures 6 and 7, I provide graphical evidence of the change in the distribution of home care visits in states with relatively unrestrictive caps (Figure 6) and in states with relatively restrictive caps (Figure 7). These figures suggest that the IPS led to a decline in the likelihood of receiving 50 or more visits, but did not substantially decrease the likelihood of receiving fewer than 50 visits. The fact that there was little change in the likelihood of receiving fewer than 50 visits could 14 I begin with HCFA s estimate that agencies that faced binding constraints would exceed the cost limits by an average of 12% (Federal Register 1999). This 12% estimate is likely to understate the initial post-policy restrictiveness, since agencies had presumably adjusted some of their behavior by Applying this conservative 12% estimate to the average pre-policy (1996) utilization level of 73.6 visits per user, I determine that the typical agency that faced a binding cap provided 7.9 visits per user (in the pre-policy period) that would not be reimbursed in the post-policy period (Health Care Financing Review 1998). Then, accounting for HCFA s estimate that the per-patient cap was not a binding constraint for 21% of agencies, I determine that an average agency in an average state faced a cap that precluded reimbursement of 6.32 visits that the average pre-policy beneficiary received (Federal Register 1999). This provides a conservative estimate of the reimbursement constraint that the typical state faced after BBA 97. Since the coefficients in the tables measure the impact of a cap that precludes reimbursement for an additional 0.25 visits per user, I multiply the coefficient in the table by (6.32*4) in order to estimate the impact for a typical state. 20

23 obscure changes in the composition of beneficiaries who received those visits. But the fact that the effects of the IPS are most visible in the upper part of the distribution suggests that the impact of the IPS may have been concentrated among those beneficiaries whose pre-policy utilization would have exceeded the per-patient caps. The theoretical framework in Section 4 suggests that the negative impact of the IPS on utilization should be stronger for relatively unhealthy beneficiaries. Therefore, in results shown in Table 4, I interact the treatment variable with a dummy variable for having high predicted costs. 15 The results for the basic estimating equation in column 3 reveal an impact on utilization among high-cost beneficiaries that is 29 times as large as the impact on low-cost beneficiaries. Moreover, the results in column 4, which control for mean reversion, suggest no decline in utilization among low-cost beneficiaries. Instead, in the typical state, beneficiaries with low predicted costs received an additional 1.5 home care visits, while beneficiaries with high predicted costs received 13.2 fewer home care visits. There are two potential explanations for the larger declines among relatively unhealthy beneficiaries. The larger declines could reflect the fact that patients with high predicted costs use about six times more home care on average than those with low predicted costs and therefore had a greater opportunity to decrease utilization. The larger declines could also reflect a behavioral effect, arising from agencies efforts to cut back on care to patients who were most likely to exceed per-patient caps. The results in Table 4 generally support the latter explanation. The results in column 3 suggest that, even as a share of mean home care use, the decline among highcost beneficiaries was greater than the decline among low-cost beneficiaries. ikewise, the 15 These regressions also control for second-order interactions between the state measure of restrictiveness, the postpolicy dummy variable, and the high predicted costs dummy variable. 21

24 results in column 4 indicate that the negative effects of the IPS on home health care usage were driven exclusively by significant negative effects among the predicted high cost beneficiaries. In Table 5, I show basic results, estimated using Equation 8, for other measures of home health utilization. 16 These results provide additional evidence that agencies responded to the IPS by differentially cutting back on care to relatively unhealthy beneficiaries. In particular, highcost beneficiaries faced a significant decline in the probability of receiving any Medicare home health care, whereas low-cost beneficiaries faced a significant increase. ikewise, high-cost beneficiaries experienced a significant decline in Medicare expenditures for home health care, whereas low-cost beneficiaries experienced a significant increase. For the typical state, the coefficients imply a $365 decline in Medicare home care spending per high-cost beneficiary and an $81 increase in Medicare home care spending per low-cost beneficiary. It is unfortunately not possible to consider the impact of the IPS on the number of home health care visits, conditional on receiving any, because the IPS had an effect on the home care participation margin. However, it is possible to determine how much of the estimated effect on unconditional Medicare home care spending can be explained by the estimated change in Medicare home care participation implied by the coefficients in column 2 of Table 5. If the predicted high-cost beneficiaries who stopped receiving any Medicare home health care after the IPS were average predicted high-cost users, the implied one percentage point decrease in the probability of receiving any home care explains only 11% of the $365 unconditional decline in Medicare home health spending among high-cost users in the typical state. Thus, the remaining 89% of the unconditional decline must be explained either by a $1,062 decrease in home care spending per user or by additional cream-skimming within the predicted high-cost beneficiaries (or by a combination of both). 16 Results estimated using Equation 7 are similar and, therefore, are not shown. 22

25 B. Effects on Other Usage and Health Outcomes Tables 6 through 8 provide evidence on substitution between home health care and other types of care and are, therefore, relevant for assessing the overall effect of the IPS on efficiency in the production of medical care. The impact of IPS restrictiveness on long-term facility care is shown in Table 6. The coefficients indicate no significant effect of the IPS on the probability of using any long-term nursing home care or on expenditures among the high-cost or low-cost beneficiaries. 17 The standard errors are sufficiently small that, for the typical state, I can reject increases in the likelihood of a high-cost beneficiary receiving any long-term facility care that are greater than 0.4 percentage points. Relative to the mean probability of any facility events for high-cost beneficiaries (27%), this maximum 0.4 percentage point increase is relatively minor. Because the results for measures of utilization of other types of care are similar to the results for long-term care facilities, I show only selected utilization measures in Tables 7 and 8. Although the results suggest no significant impact of the IPS on any of these expenditure measures, the standard errors are sufficiently large that it is impossible to reject a sizeable impact. Thus, the results for substitution towards other care are merely suggestive that there was no impact. Because the IPS led to a large decline in home care usage among some of Medicare s most unhealthy beneficiaries, it provides a good opportunity to assess the benefits of home health care for beneficiary health outcomes. I use several measures of health, including body mass index (BMI), functional limitations and mortality. Table 9 shows the impact on BMI, the 17 The finding of no substitution towards long-term facilities could, in theory, reflect the existence of excess demand for nursing home beds that has been previously reported. However, Grabowski (2001) summarizes the most recent evidence, which suggests a shift away from excess demand in the nursing home market in the 1980s and 1990s. Nursing home occupancy rates were roughly 89% in 1996 (Harrington, Swan et al. 1998). 23

26 probability of being underweight, and the probability of being overweight. Table 10 shows the effects on reported difficulties with three activities: stooping or kneeling, lifting 10 pounds, and walking 2-3 blocks. 18 The dependent variable in each column is a dummy variable for reporting a lot of difficulty or an inability to perform the activity. In each case, there is no significant effect of the IPS. Finally, in results that are not reported in tables, I estimate effects on mortality, but do not find any impact. These measures of health outcomes are obviously quite coarse and, thus, should be interpreted as suggestive rather than conclusive. Nevertheless, they do not suggest any adverse health consequences associated with declines in home care. There are several possible explanations for finding no evidence of a negative impact on health. For instance, it may be the case that the visits that were cut back after the IPS were less medically necessary than the visits that were not cut back. 19 Another possible explanation is that the decline in publicly provided home health care visits led to an increase in informal care by family and friends. This explanation is not directly testable in the data. In addition, there may have been impacts on aspects of health or well-being that are not measured in this data, or impacts that affected only a small subset of patients rather than the overall Medicare population. Another possible explanation for these findings is that individuals offset the reduction in Medicare-provided home health care visits by obtaining home health care through other sources of payment. Thus, in Table 11, I show the impact of the IPS on total home health care spending, and decompose the impact among the three largest sources of payment for home care: Medicare, 18 These regressions necessarily exclude functional limitations from the set of explanatory variables and from the home care cost prediction equations. This change raises the question of whether functional limitations should be used as control variables in any regressions, since they are potential outcomes. Results that are not shown in the tables reveal that my findings are not sensitive to the exclusion of functional limitation control variables. 19 McCall et al. (2001) report that the composition of Medicare home health visits shifted away from home health aide visits and towards skilled care after BBA 97. If the home health aide visits provided the least marginal medical value, it may not be surprising that there are no observable adverse impacts on health status. 24

27 Medicaid and beneficiary out-of-pocket expenditures. 20 I do not find a significant increase in Medicaid home health care spending, but I do find a significant increase in out-of-pocket home health spending among high-cost beneficiaries. In particular, twenty-two percent of the estimated decline in Medicare spending among high-cost beneficiaries was offset by increases in out-of-pocket expenditures. This finding is consistent with aggregate data, which indicate that out-of-pocket expenditures for home- and community-based long-term care for the elderly nearly doubled between 1995 and 2000, rising from $6 billion to $11 billion (U.S. Congress 1998, 2000). The evidence, therefore, suggests that some of the cost savings from the IPS were not, in the broadest terms, cost savings; rather, the costs were shifted to other payers. Given that some of the decline in Medicare home health care was offset by increases in out-of-pocket expenditures, an important question is whether lower income beneficiaries who may not be able to afford to pay for their own home health care experienced larger declines in home health care. Table 12 shows key regression coefficients separately for beneficiaries with incomes below and above the poverty line. Columns 1 and 4 show the means of the dependent variables for the low- and high-income sub-samples. Columns 2 and 5 show the coefficient on the interaction between a post-policy dummy variable and the state-level restrictiveness measure. Columns 3 and 6 show the coefficient (from the same regression) on the interaction between the predicted high-cost dummy variable, the post-policy dummy variable, and the restrictiveness measure. The most striking difference between high- and low-income beneficiaries is that lowincome beneficiaries did not offset Medicare spending reductions with out-of-pocket expenditures. Rather, the increases in out-of-pocket expenditures were concentrated among the 20 There is likely to be more under-reporting in the non-medicare payments for home health care, because these data are based only on survey responses, rather than administrative data. 25

Working Paper Series

Working Paper Series The Financial Benefits of Critical Access Hospital Conversion for FY 1999 and FY 2000 Converters Working Paper Series Jeffrey Stensland, Ph.D. Project HOPE (and currently MedPAC) Gestur Davidson, Ph.D.

More information

Dual Eligibles: Medicaid s Role in Filling Medicare s Gaps

Dual Eligibles: Medicaid s Role in Filling Medicare s Gaps I S S U E P A P E R kaiser commission on medicaid and the uninsured March 2004 Dual Eligibles: Medicaid s Role in Filling Medicare s Gaps In 2000, over 7 million people were dual eligibles, low-income

More information

paymentbasics The IPPS payment rates are intended to cover the costs that reasonably efficient providers would incur in furnishing highquality

paymentbasics The IPPS payment rates are intended to cover the costs that reasonably efficient providers would incur in furnishing highquality Hospital ACUTE inpatient services system basics Revised: October 2015 This document does not reflect proposed legislation or regulatory actions. 425 I Street, NW Suite 701 Washington, DC 20001 ph: 202-220-3700

More information

Final Report No. 101 April Trends in Skilled Nursing Facility and Swing Bed Use in Rural Areas Following the Medicare Modernization Act of 2003

Final Report No. 101 April Trends in Skilled Nursing Facility and Swing Bed Use in Rural Areas Following the Medicare Modernization Act of 2003 Final Report No. 101 April 2011 Trends in Skilled Nursing Facility and Swing Bed Use in Rural Areas Following the Medicare Modernization Act of 2003 The North Carolina Rural Health Research & Policy Analysis

More information

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Order Code RS20386 Updated April 16, 2001 Medicare's Skilled Nursing Facility Benefit Summary Heidi G. Yacker Information Research Specialist Information

More information

The Effects of Medicare Home Health Outlier Payment. Policy Changes on Older Adults with Type 1 Diabetes. Hyunjee Kim

The Effects of Medicare Home Health Outlier Payment. Policy Changes on Older Adults with Type 1 Diabetes. Hyunjee Kim The Effects of Medicare Home Health Outlier Payment Policy Changes on Older Adults with Type 1 Diabetes Hyunjee Kim 1 Abstract There have been struggles to find a reimbursement system that achieves a seemingly

More information

Prepared for North Gunther Hospital Medicare ID August 06, 2012

Prepared for North Gunther Hospital Medicare ID August 06, 2012 Prepared for North Gunther Hospital Medicare ID 000001 August 06, 2012 TABLE OF CONTENTS Introduction: Benchmarking Your Hospital 3 Section 1: Hospital Operating Costs 5 Section 2: Margins 10 Section 3:

More information

State of Kansas Department of Social and Rehabilitation Services Department on Aging Kansas Health Policy Authority

State of Kansas Department of Social and Rehabilitation Services Department on Aging Kansas Health Policy Authority State of Kansas Department of Social and Rehabilitation Services Department on Aging Kansas Health Policy Authority Notice of Proposed Nursing Facility Medicaid Rates for State Fiscal Year 2010; Methodology

More information

time to replace adjusted discharges

time to replace adjusted discharges REPRINT May 2014 William O. Cleverley healthcare financial management association hfma.org time to replace adjusted discharges A new metric for measuring total hospital volume correlates significantly

More information

Health Care Spending Growth under the Prospective. Care

Health Care Spending Growth under the Prospective. Care Health Care Spending Growth under the Prospective Payment System: Evidence from Medicare Home Health Care Hyunjee Kim 1 Abstract This paper explores the causes of the dramatic rise in total Medicare home

More information

Medicare Spending and Rehospitalization for Chronically Ill Medicare Beneficiaries: Home Health Use Compared to Other Post-Acute Care Settings

Medicare Spending and Rehospitalization for Chronically Ill Medicare Beneficiaries: Home Health Use Compared to Other Post-Acute Care Settings Medicare Spending and Rehospitalization for Chronically Ill Medicare Beneficiaries: Home Health Use Compared to Other Post-Acute Care Settings Executive Summary The Alliance for Home Health Quality and

More information

paymentbasics Defining the inpatient acute care products Medicare buys Under the IPPS, Medicare sets perdischarge

paymentbasics Defining the inpatient acute care products Medicare buys Under the IPPS, Medicare sets perdischarge Hospital ACUTE inpatient services system basics Revised: October 2007 This document does not reflect proposed legislation or regulatory actions. 601 New Jersey Ave., NW Suite 9000 Washington, DC 20001

More information

Guidance for Developing Payment Models for COMPASS Collaborative Care Management for Depression and Diabetes and/or Cardiovascular Disease

Guidance for Developing Payment Models for COMPASS Collaborative Care Management for Depression and Diabetes and/or Cardiovascular Disease Guidance for Developing Payment Models for COMPASS Collaborative Care Management for Depression and Diabetes and/or Cardiovascular Disease Introduction Within the COMPASS (Care Of Mental, Physical, And

More information

Fertility Response to the Tax Treatment of Children

Fertility Response to the Tax Treatment of Children Fertility Response to the Tax Treatment of Children Kevin J. Mumford Purdue University Paul Thomas Purdue University April 2016 Abstract This paper uses variation in the child tax subsidy implicit in US

More information

Joint Replacement Outweighs Other Factors in Determining CMS Readmission Penalties

Joint Replacement Outweighs Other Factors in Determining CMS Readmission Penalties Joint Replacement Outweighs Other Factors in Determining CMS Readmission Penalties Abstract Many hospital leaders would like to pinpoint future readmission-related penalties and the return on investment

More information

Scottish Hospital Standardised Mortality Ratio (HSMR)

Scottish Hospital Standardised Mortality Ratio (HSMR) ` 2016 Scottish Hospital Standardised Mortality Ratio (HSMR) Methodology & Specification Document Page 1 of 14 Document Control Version 0.1 Date Issued July 2016 Author(s) Quality Indicators Team Comments

More information

Community Performance Report

Community Performance Report : Wenatchee Current Year: Q1 217 through Q4 217 Qualis Health Communities for Safer Transitions of Care Performance Report : Wenatchee Includes Data Through: Q4 217 Report Created: May 3, 218 Purpose of

More information

Special Open Door Forum Participation Instructions: Dial: Reference Conference ID#:

Special Open Door Forum Participation Instructions: Dial: Reference Conference ID#: Page 1 Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services Hospital Value-Based Purchasing Program Special Open Door Forum: FY 2013 Program Wednesday, July 27, 2011 1:00 p.m.-3:00 p.m. ET The Centers for Medicare

More information

Understanding Risk Adjustment in Medicare Advantage

Understanding Risk Adjustment in Medicare Advantage Understanding Risk Adjustment in Medicare Advantage ISSUE BRIEF JUNE 2017 Risk adjustment is an essential mechanism used in health insurance programs to account for the overall health and expected medical

More information

Minnesota health care price transparency laws and rules

Minnesota health care price transparency laws and rules Minnesota health care price transparency laws and rules Minnesota Statutes 2013 62J.81 DISCLOSURE OF PAYMENTS FOR HEALTH CARE SERVICES. Subdivision 1.Required disclosure of estimated payment. (a) A health

More information

You re In or You re Out: Determining Winners and Losers Under a Global Payment System

You re In or You re Out: Determining Winners and Losers Under a Global Payment System You re In or You re Out: Determining Winners and Losers Under a Global Payment System PRESENTED TO: Northeast Home Health Leadership Summit PRESENTED BY: Allen Dobson, Ph.D. PREPARED BY: Allen Dobson,

More information

MEDICARE ENROLLMENT, HEALTH STATUS, SERVICE USE AND PAYMENT DATA FOR AMERICAN INDIANS & ALASKA NATIVES

MEDICARE ENROLLMENT, HEALTH STATUS, SERVICE USE AND PAYMENT DATA FOR AMERICAN INDIANS & ALASKA NATIVES American Indian & Alaska Native Data Project of the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services Tribal Technical Advisory Group MEDICARE ENROLLMENT, HEALTH STATUS, SERVICE USE AND PAYMENT DATA FOR AMERICAN

More information

Creating a Patient-Centered Payment System to Support Higher-Quality, More Affordable Health Care. Harold D. Miller

Creating a Patient-Centered Payment System to Support Higher-Quality, More Affordable Health Care. Harold D. Miller Creating a Patient-Centered Payment System to Support Higher-Quality, More Affordable Health Care Harold D. Miller First Edition October 2017 CONTENTS EXECUTIVE SUMMARY... i I. THE QUEST TO PAY FOR VALUE

More information

Introduction and Executive Summary

Introduction and Executive Summary Introduction and Executive Summary 1. Introduction and Executive Summary. Hospital length of stay (LOS) varies markedly and persistently across geographic areas in the United States. This phenomenon is

More information

Free to Choose? Reform and Demand Response in the British National Health Service

Free to Choose? Reform and Demand Response in the British National Health Service Free to Choose? Reform and Demand Response in the British National Health Service Martin Gaynor Carol Propper Stephan Seiler Carnegie Mellon University, University of Bristol and NBER Imperial College,

More information

BACKGROUND PAPER: RURAL AND URBAN DIFFERENCES IN NURSING HOME AND SKILLED NURSING SUPPLY

BACKGROUND PAPER: RURAL AND URBAN DIFFERENCES IN NURSING HOME AND SKILLED NURSING SUPPLY BACKGROUND PAPER: RURAL AND URBAN DIFFERENCES IN NURSING HOME AND SKILLED NURSING SUPPLY Working Paper No. 74 WORKING PAPER SERIES North Carolina Rural Health Research and Policy Analysis Center Cecil

More information

Simplifying Federal Student Aid

Simplifying Federal Student Aid E D U C A T I O N A N D T R A I N I N G Simplifying Federal Student Aid A Closer Look at Pell Formulas with Two Inputs Kim Rueben, Sarah Gault, and Sandy Baum April 2016 This brief examines proposals that

More information

2014 MASTER PROJECT LIST

2014 MASTER PROJECT LIST Promoting Integrated Care for Dual Eligibles (PRIDE) This project addressed a set of organizational challenges that high performing plans must resolve in order to scale up to serve larger numbers of dual

More information

Re: Rewarding Provider Performance: Aligning Incentives in Medicare

Re: Rewarding Provider Performance: Aligning Incentives in Medicare September 25, 2006 Institute of Medicine 500 Fifth Street NW Washington DC 20001 Re: Rewarding Provider Performance: Aligning Incentives in Medicare The American College of Physicians (ACP), representing

More information

The Number of People With Chronic Conditions Is Rapidly Increasing

The Number of People With Chronic Conditions Is Rapidly Increasing Section 1 Demographics and Prevalence The Number of People With Chronic Conditions Is Rapidly Increasing In 2000, 125 million Americans had one or more chronic conditions. Number of People With Chronic

More information

Measuring the relationship between ICT use and income inequality in Chile

Measuring the relationship between ICT use and income inequality in Chile Measuring the relationship between ICT use and income inequality in Chile By Carolina Flores c.a.flores@mail.utexas.edu University of Texas Inequality Project Working Paper 26 October 26, 2003. Abstract:

More information

Making the Business Case

Making the Business Case Making the Business Case for Payment and Delivery Reform Harold D. Miller Center for Healthcare Quality and Payment Reform To learn more about RWJFsupported payment reform activities, visit RWJF s Payment

More information

HCCA South Central Regional Annual Conference November 21, 2014 Nashville, TN. Post Acute Provider Specific Sections from OIG Work Plans

HCCA South Central Regional Annual Conference November 21, 2014 Nashville, TN. Post Acute Provider Specific Sections from OIG Work Plans HCCA South Central Regional Annual Conference November 21, 2014 Nashville, TN Kelly Priegnitz # Chris Puri # Kim Looney Post Acute Provider Specific Sections from 2012-2015 OIG Work Plans I. NURSING HOMES

More information

The Life-Cycle Profile of Time Spent on Job Search

The Life-Cycle Profile of Time Spent on Job Search The Life-Cycle Profile of Time Spent on Job Search By Mark Aguiar, Erik Hurst and Loukas Karabarbounis How do unemployed individuals allocate their time spent on job search over their life-cycle? While

More information

The President s and Other Bipartisan Proposals to Reform Medicare: Post-Acute Care (PAC) Reform. Summary

The President s and Other Bipartisan Proposals to Reform Medicare: Post-Acute Care (PAC) Reform. Summary Current Law The President s and Other Bipartisan Proposals to Reform Medicare: Post-Acute Care (PAC) Reform Summary Home Health Agencies Under current law, beneficiaries who are generally restricted to

More information

Medicare P4P -- Medicare Quality Reporting, Incentive and Penalty Programs

Medicare P4P -- Medicare Quality Reporting, Incentive and Penalty Programs Medicare P4P -- Medicare Quality Reporting, Incentive and Penalty Programs Presenter: Daniel J. Hettich King & Spalding; Washington, DC dhettich@kslaw.com 1 I. Introduction Evolution of Medicare as a Purchaser

More information

London, Brunei Gallery, October 3 5, Measurement of Health Output experiences from the Norwegian National Accounts

London, Brunei Gallery, October 3 5, Measurement of Health Output experiences from the Norwegian National Accounts Session Number : 2 Session Title : Health - recent experiences in measuring output growth Session Chair : Sir T. Atkinson Paper prepared for the joint OECD/ONS/Government of Norway workshop Measurement

More information

A Primer on Activity-Based Funding

A Primer on Activity-Based Funding A Primer on Activity-Based Funding Introduction and Background Canada is ranked sixth among the richest countries in the world in terms of the proportion of gross domestic product (GDP) spent on health

More information

Hospital Inpatient Quality Reporting (IQR) Program

Hospital Inpatient Quality Reporting (IQR) Program Hospital Readmissions Reduction Program Early Look Hospital-Specific Reports Questions and Answers Transcript Speakers Tamyra Garcia Deputy Division Director Division of Value, Incentives, and Quality

More information

The Medicare Prospective Payntent Systent

The Medicare Prospective Payntent Systent The Medicare Prospective Payntent Systent (Medicare, occupational therapy, prospective payment systems, third party reimbursement) Susan J. Scott In 1983 Congress adopted the most significant change in

More information

This PDF is a selec on from a published volume from the Na onal Bureau of Economic Research. Volume Title: Discoveries in the Economics of Aging

This PDF is a selec on from a published volume from the Na onal Bureau of Economic Research. Volume Title: Discoveries in the Economics of Aging This PDF is a selec on from a published volume from the Na onal Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Discoveries in the Economics of Aging Volume Author/Editor: David A. Wise, editor Volume Publisher:

More information

The Home Health Groupings Model (HHGM)

The Home Health Groupings Model (HHGM) The Home Health Groupings Model (HHGM) September 5, 017 PRESENTED BY: Al Dobson, Ph.D. PREPARED BY: Al Dobson, Ph.D., Alex Hartzman, M.P.A, M.P.H., Kimberly Rhodes, M.A., Sarmistha Pal, Ph.D., Sung Kim,

More information

Licensed Nurses in Florida: Trends and Longitudinal Analysis

Licensed Nurses in Florida: Trends and Longitudinal Analysis Licensed Nurses in Florida: 2007-2009 Trends and Longitudinal Analysis March 2009 Addressing Nurse Workforce Issues for the Health of Florida www.flcenterfornursing.org March 2009 2007-2009 Licensure Trends

More information

Trends in Skilled Nursing and Swing-bed Use in Rural Areas,

Trends in Skilled Nursing and Swing-bed Use in Rural Areas, Trends in Skilled Nursing and Swing-bed Use in Rural Areas, 1996- Working Paper No. 83 WORKING PAPER SERIES North Carolina Rural Health Research and Policy Analysis Center Cecil G. Sheps Center for Health

More information

Differences in employment histories between employed and unemployed job seekers

Differences in employment histories between employed and unemployed job seekers 8 Differences in employment histories between employed and unemployed job seekers Simonetta Longhi Mark Taylor Institute for Social and Economic Research University of Essex No. 2010-32 21 September 2010

More information

Medicaid and Block Grant Financing Compared

Medicaid and Block Grant Financing Compared P O L I C Y kaiser commission on medicaid a n d t h e uninsured January 2004 B R I E F Medicaid and Block Grant Financing Compared State and federal budget pressures, rising health care costs, and new

More information

THE IMPACT OF BBA, BIPA and MEDICARE+CHOICE ON LTC (Why Medicare/Medicare Supplement is SHORT-TERM CARE)

THE IMPACT OF BBA, BIPA and MEDICARE+CHOICE ON LTC (Why Medicare/Medicare Supplement is SHORT-TERM CARE) THE IMPACT OF BBA, BIPA and MEDICARE+CHOICE ON LTC (Why Medicare/Medicare Supplement is SHORT-TERM CARE) (For a complete description of Medicare, Medicare supplement and Medicare+Choice, see Appendix A

More information

Summary of U.S. Senate Finance Committee Health Reform Bill

Summary of U.S. Senate Finance Committee Health Reform Bill Summary of U.S. Senate Finance Committee Health Reform Bill September 2009 The following is a summary of the major hospital and health system provisions included in the Finance Committee bill, the America

More information

Lessons from Medicaid Pay-for- Performance in Nursing Homes

Lessons from Medicaid Pay-for- Performance in Nursing Homes Lessons from Medicaid Pay-for- Performance in Nursing Homes R. Tamara Konetzka, PhD Based on work with Rachel M. Werner, Daniel Polsky, Meghan Skira Funded by National Institute of Aging (R01 AG034182,

More information

Executive Summary. This Project

Executive Summary. This Project Executive Summary The Health Care Financing Administration (HCFA) has had a long-term commitment to work towards implementation of a per-episode prospective payment approach for Medicare home health services,

More information

Health Economics Program

Health Economics Program Health Economics Program Issue Paper July 2000 Home Care Provider Trends in Minnesota: 1994-1999 Background Minnesota has an interesting history with regard to home care trends. Although Medicare beneficiaries

More information

August 25, Dear Ms. Verma:

August 25, Dear Ms. Verma: Seema Verma Administrator Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services Hubert H. Humphrey Building 200 Independence Avenue, S.W. Room 445-G Washington, DC 20201 CMS 1686 ANPRM, Medicare Program; Prospective

More information

Cumulative Out-of-Pocket Health Care Expenses After the Age of 70

Cumulative Out-of-Pocket Health Care Expenses After the Age of 70 April 3, 2018 No. 446 Cumulative Out-of-Pocket Health Care Expenses After the Age of 70 By Sudipto Banerjee, Employee Benefit Research Institute A T A G L A N C E This study estimates how much retirees

More information

THE ROLE OF HOSPITAL HETEROGENEITY IN MEASURING MARGINAL RETURNS TO MEDICAL CARE: A REPLY TO BARRECA, GULDI, LINDO, AND WADDELL

THE ROLE OF HOSPITAL HETEROGENEITY IN MEASURING MARGINAL RETURNS TO MEDICAL CARE: A REPLY TO BARRECA, GULDI, LINDO, AND WADDELL THE ROLE OF HOSPITAL HETEROGENEITY IN MEASURING MARGINAL RETURNS TO MEDICAL CARE: A REPLY TO BARRECA, GULDI, LINDO, AND WADDELL DOUGLAS ALMOND JOSEPH J. DOYLE, JR. AMANDA E. KOWALSKI HEIDI WILLIAMS In

More information

FISCAL FEDERALISM. How State and Local Governments Differ from the National Government

FISCAL FEDERALISM. How State and Local Governments Differ from the National Government FISCAL FEDERALISM devolution: The passing or transferring of fiscal responsibilities and authority from one level of government to another. In August 1996, Congress approved legislation ending 60-year

More information

Medicaid HCBS/FE Home Telehealth Pilot Final Report for Study Years 1-3 (September 2007 June 2010)

Medicaid HCBS/FE Home Telehealth Pilot Final Report for Study Years 1-3 (September 2007 June 2010) Medicaid HCBS/FE Home Telehealth Pilot Final Report for Study Years 1-3 (September 2007 June 2010) Completed November 30, 2010 Ryan Spaulding, PhD Director Gordon Alloway Research Associate Center for

More information

The Role of Analytics in the Development of a Successful Readmissions Program

The Role of Analytics in the Development of a Successful Readmissions Program The Role of Analytics in the Development of a Successful Readmissions Program Pierre Yong, MD, MPH Director, Quality Measurement & Value-Based Incentives Group Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services

More information

EuroHOPE: Hospital performance

EuroHOPE: Hospital performance EuroHOPE: Hospital performance Unto Häkkinen, Research Professor Centre for Health and Social Economics, CHESS National Institute for Health and Welfare, THL What and how EuroHOPE does? Applies both the

More information

September 25, Via Regulations.gov

September 25, Via Regulations.gov September 25, 2017 Via Regulations.gov The Honorable Seema Verma Administrator Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services 7500 Security Boulevard Baltimore, MD 21244-1850 RE: Medicare and Medicaid Programs;

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOUSEHOLD RESPONSES TO PUBLIC HOME CARE PROGRAMS. Peter C. Coyte Mark Stabile

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOUSEHOLD RESPONSES TO PUBLIC HOME CARE PROGRAMS. Peter C. Coyte Mark Stabile NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOUSEHOLD RESPONSES TO PUBLIC HOME CARE PROGRAMS Peter C. Coyte Mark Stabile Working Paper 8523 http://www.nber.org/papers/w8523 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

September 16, The Honorable Pat Tiberi. Chairman

September 16, The Honorable Pat Tiberi. Chairman 1201 L Street, NW, Washington, DC 20005 T: 202-842-4444 F: 202-842-3860 www.ahcancal.org September 16, 2016 The Honorable Kevin Brady The Honorable Ron Kind Chairman U.S. House of Representatives House

More information

Issue Brief. Findings from HSC INSURED AMERICANS DRIVE SURGE IN EMERGENCY DEPARTMENT VISITS. Trends in Emergency Department Use

Issue Brief. Findings from HSC INSURED AMERICANS DRIVE SURGE IN EMERGENCY DEPARTMENT VISITS. Trends in Emergency Department Use Issue Brief Findings from HSC INSURED AMERICANS DRIVE SURGE IN EMERGENCY DEPARTMENT VISITS by Peter Cunningham and Jessica May Visits to hospital emergency departments (EDs) have increased greatly in recent

More information

Massachusetts Community Hospitals - A Comparative Economic Analysis

Massachusetts Community Hospitals - A Comparative Economic Analysis Massachusetts Community Hospitals - A Comparative Economic Analysis Rising Demand vs. Falling Profitability By Edward Moscovitch Prepared for the Massachusetts Council of Community Hospitals October 2005

More information

Effects of the Ten Percent Cap in Medicare Home Health Care on Treatment Intensity and Patient Discharge Status

Effects of the Ten Percent Cap in Medicare Home Health Care on Treatment Intensity and Patient Discharge Status Health Services Research Health Research and Educational Trust DOI: 10.1111/1475-6773.12290 RESEARCH ARTICLE Effects of the Ten Percent Cap in Medicare Home Health Care on Treatment Intensity and Patient

More information

Summary and Analysis of CMS Proposed and Final Rules versus AAOS Comments: Comprehensive Care for Joint Replacement Model (CJR)

Summary and Analysis of CMS Proposed and Final Rules versus AAOS Comments: Comprehensive Care for Joint Replacement Model (CJR) Summary and Analysis of CMS Proposed and Final Rules versus AAOS Comments: Comprehensive Care for Joint Replacement Model (CJR) The table below summarizes the specific provisions noted in the Medicare

More information

MEDICARE FFY 2017 PPS PROPOSED RULES OVERVIEW OHA Finance/PFS Webinar Series. May 10, 2016

MEDICARE FFY 2017 PPS PROPOSED RULES OVERVIEW OHA Finance/PFS Webinar Series. May 10, 2016 MEDICARE FFY 2017 PPS PROPOSED RULES OVERVIEW 2016 OHA Finance/PFS Webinar Series May 10, 2016 Spring is Medicare PPS Proposed Rules Season Inpatient Hospital Long-Term Acute Care Hospital Inpatient Rehabilitation

More information

2016 Edition. Upper Payment Limits and Medicaid Capitation Rates for Programs of All-Inclusive Care for the Elderly (PACE )

2016 Edition. Upper Payment Limits and Medicaid Capitation Rates for Programs of All-Inclusive Care for the Elderly (PACE ) 2016 Edition Upper Payment Limits and Medicaid Capitation Rates for Programs of All-Inclusive Care for the Elderly (PACE ) R ABSTRACT The Program of All-Inclusive Care for the Elderly (PACE ) is a federal

More information

HOSPITAL SYSTEM READMISSIONS

HOSPITAL SYSTEM READMISSIONS HOSPITAL SYSTEM READMISSIONS Student Author Cody Mullen graduated in 2012 from Purdue University with a bachelor s degree in interdisciplinary science, focusing on statistics and healthcare. During the

More information

Trends in hospital reforms and reflections for China

Trends in hospital reforms and reflections for China Trends in hospital reforms and reflections for China Beijing, 18 February 2012 Henk Bekedam, Director Health Sector Development with input from Sarah Barber, and OECD: Michael Borowitz & Raphaëlle Bisiaux

More information

Integrated Health System

Integrated Health System Integrated Health System Please note that the views expressed are those of the conference speakers and do not necessarily reflect the views of the American Hospital Association and Health Forum. Page 2

More information

Aging in Place: Do Older Americans Act Title III Services Reach Those Most Likely to Enter Nursing Homes? Nursing Home Predictors

Aging in Place: Do Older Americans Act Title III Services Reach Those Most Likely to Enter Nursing Homes? Nursing Home Predictors T I M E L Y I N F O R M A T I O N F R O M M A T H E M A T I C A Improving public well-being by conducting high quality, objective research and surveys JULY 2010 Number 1 Helping Vulnerable Seniors Thrive

More information

Appendix. We used matched-pair cluster-randomization to assign the. twenty-eight towns to intervention and control. Each cluster,

Appendix. We used matched-pair cluster-randomization to assign the. twenty-eight towns to intervention and control. Each cluster, Yip W, Powell-Jackson T, Chen W, Hu M, Fe E, Hu M, et al. Capitation combined with payfor-performance improves antibiotic prescribing practices in rural China. Health Aff (Millwood). 2014;33(3). Published

More information

Is there a Trade-off between Costs and Quality in Hospital

Is there a Trade-off between Costs and Quality in Hospital Is there a Trade-off between Costs and Quality in Hospital Care? Evidence from Germany and the US COHERE Opening Seminar, Odense, May 21 2011 Prof. Dr. Jonas Schreyögg, Hamburg Center for Health Economics,

More information

Analysis of 340B Disproportionate Share Hospital Services to Low- Income Patients

Analysis of 340B Disproportionate Share Hospital Services to Low- Income Patients Analysis of 340B Disproportionate Share Hospital Services to Low- Income Patients March 12, 2018 Prepared for: 340B Health Prepared by: L&M Policy Research, LLC 1743 Connecticut Ave NW, Suite 200 Washington,

More information

The Interactive Effect of Medicare Inpatient and Outpatient Reimbursement

The Interactive Effect of Medicare Inpatient and Outpatient Reimbursement The Interactive Effect of Medicare Inpatient and Outpatient Reimbursement JOB MARKET PAPER Andrew Elzinga November 12, 2015 Abstract Hospital care is characterized by inpatient and outpatient departments;

More information

PANELS AND PANEL EQUITY

PANELS AND PANEL EQUITY PANELS AND PANEL EQUITY Our patients are very clear about what they want: the opportunity to choose a primary care provider access to that PCP when they choose a quality healthcare experience a good value

More information

Development of Updated Models of Non-Therapy Ancillary Costs

Development of Updated Models of Non-Therapy Ancillary Costs Development of Updated Models of Non-Therapy Ancillary Costs Doug Wissoker A. Bowen Garrett A memo by staff from the Urban Institute for the Medicare Payment Advisory Commission Urban Institute MedPAC

More information

Annex A: State Level Analysis: Selection of Indicators, Frontier Estimation, Setting of Xmin, Xp, and Yp Values, and Data Sources

Annex A: State Level Analysis: Selection of Indicators, Frontier Estimation, Setting of Xmin, Xp, and Yp Values, and Data Sources Annex A: State Level Analysis: Selection of Indicators, Frontier Estimation, Setting of Xmin, Xp, and Yp Values, and Data Sources Right to Food: Whereas in the international assessment the percentage of

More information

Reducing emergency admissions

Reducing emergency admissions A picture of the National Audit Office logo Report by the Comptroller and Auditor General Department of Health & Social Care NHS England Reducing emergency admissions HC 833 SESSION 2017 2019 2 MARCH 2018

More information

A Report of The Heritage Center for Data Analysis

A Report of The Heritage Center for Data Analysis A Report of The Heritage Center for Data Analysis MORE H-1B VISAS, MORE AMERICAN JOBS, A BETTER ECONOMY JAMES SHERK AND GUINEVERE NELL CDA08-01 April 30, 2008 214 Massachusetts Avenue, NE Washington, D.C.

More information

06-01 FORM HCFA WORKSHEET S - HOME HEALTH AGENCY COST REPORT The intermediary indicates in the appropriate box whether this is the

06-01 FORM HCFA WORKSHEET S - HOME HEALTH AGENCY COST REPORT The intermediary indicates in the appropriate box whether this is the 06-01 FORM HCFA-1728-94 3204 3203. WORKSHEET S - HOME HEALTH AGENCY COST REPORT The intermediary indicates in the appropriate box whether this is the initial cost report (first cost report filed for the

More information

Volume URL: Chapter Title: The Concentration of Medical Spending: An Update

Volume URL:   Chapter Title: The Concentration of Medical Spending: An Update This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Themes in the Economics of Aging Volume Author/Editor: David A. Wise, editor Volume Publisher:

More information

Medicare Home Health Prospective Payment System

Medicare Home Health Prospective Payment System Medicare Home Health Prospective Payment System Payment Rule Brief Final Rule Program Year: CY 2013 Overview On November 8, 2012, the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS) officially released

More information

Medicare Skilled Nursing Facility Prospective Payment System

Medicare Skilled Nursing Facility Prospective Payment System Final Rule Summary Medicare Skilled Nursing Facility Prospective Payment System Program Year: FY2019 August 2018 1 TABLE OF CONTENTS Overview and Resources... 2 SNF Payment Rates... 2 Wage Index and Labor-Related

More information

Patient Selection Under Incomplete Case Mix Adjustment: Evidence from the Hospital Value-based Purchasing Program

Patient Selection Under Incomplete Case Mix Adjustment: Evidence from the Hospital Value-based Purchasing Program Patient Selection Under Incomplete Case Mix Adjustment: Evidence from the Hospital Value-based Purchasing Program Lizhong Peng October, 2014 Disclaimer: Pennsylvania inpatient data are from the Pennsylvania

More information

Asset Transfer and Nursing Home Use

Asset Transfer and Nursing Home Use I S S U E kaiser commission on medicaid and the uninsured November 2005 P A P E R Issue Asset Transfer and Nursing Home Use Medicaid paid for nearly half of the $183 billion spent nationally for long-term

More information

snapshot Improving Experience of Care Scores Alone is NOT the Answer: Hospitals Need a Patient-Centric Foundation

snapshot Improving Experience of Care Scores Alone is NOT the Answer: Hospitals Need a Patient-Centric Foundation SATISFACTION snapshot news, views & ideas from the leader in healthcare satisfaction measurement The Satisfaction Snapshot is a monthly electronic bulletin freely available to all those involved or interested

More information

Frequently Asked Questions (FAQ) The Harvard Pilgrim Independence Plan SM

Frequently Asked Questions (FAQ) The Harvard Pilgrim Independence Plan SM Frequently Asked Questions (FAQ) The Harvard Pilgrim Independence Plan SM Plan Year: July 2010 June 2011 Background The Harvard Pilgrim Independence Plan was developed in 2006 for the Commonwealth of Massachusetts

More information

Mental Health Services Provided in Specialty Mental Health Organizations, 2004

Mental Health Services Provided in Specialty Mental Health Organizations, 2004 Mental Health Services Provided in Specialty Mental Health Organizations, 2004 Mental Health Services Provided in Specialty Mental Health Organizations, 2004 U.S. Department of Health and Human Services

More information

how competition can improve management quality and save lives

how competition can improve management quality and save lives NHS hospitals in England are rarely closed in constituencies where the governing party has a slender majority. This means that for near random reasons, those parts of the country have more competition

More information

Fleet and Marine Corps Health Risk Assessment, 02 January December 31, 2015

Fleet and Marine Corps Health Risk Assessment, 02 January December 31, 2015 Fleet and Marine Corps Health Risk Assessment, 02 January December 31, 2015 Executive Summary The Fleet and Marine Corps Health Risk Appraisal is a 22-question anonymous self-assessment of the most common

More information

3M Health Information Systems. 3M Clinical Risk Groups: Measuring risk, managing care

3M Health Information Systems. 3M Clinical Risk Groups: Measuring risk, managing care 3M Health Information Systems 3M Clinical Risk Groups: Measuring risk, managing care 3M Clinical Risk Groups: Measuring risk, managing care Overview The 3M Clinical Risk Groups (CRGs) are a population

More information

September 22, 2017 VIA ELECTRONIC SUBMISSION

September 22, 2017 VIA ELECTRONIC SUBMISSION September 22, 2017 VIA ELECTRONIC SUBMISSION The Honorable Seema Verma Administrator Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services Department of Health and Human Services 7500 Security Boulevard Baltimore,

More information

Health and Long-Term Care Use Patterns for Ohio s Dual Eligible Population Experiencing Chronic Disability

Health and Long-Term Care Use Patterns for Ohio s Dual Eligible Population Experiencing Chronic Disability Health and Long-Term Care Use Patterns for Ohio s Dual Eligible Population Experiencing Chronic Disability Shahla A. Mehdizadeh, Ph.D. 1 Robert A. Applebaum, Ph.D. 2 Gregg Warshaw, M.D. 3 Jane K. Straker,

More information

Policies for Controlling Volume January 9, 2014

Policies for Controlling Volume January 9, 2014 Policies for Controlling Volume January 9, 2014 The Maryland Hospital Association Policies for controlling volume Introduction Under the proposed demonstration model, the HSCRC will move from a regulatory

More information

National Council on Disability

National Council on Disability An independent federal agency making recommendations to the President and Congress to enhance the quality of life for all Americans with disabilities and their families. Analysis and Recommendations for

More information

TC911 SERVICE COORDINATION PROGRAM

TC911 SERVICE COORDINATION PROGRAM TC911 SERVICE COORDINATION PROGRAM ANALYSIS OF PROGRAM IMPACTS & SUSTAINABILITY CONDUCTED BY: Bill Wright, PhD Sarah Tran, MPH Jennifer Matson, MPH The Center for Outcomes Research & Education Providence

More information

Market Ownership Structure and Service Provision. Pattern Change over Time: Evidence from Medicare. Home Health Care

Market Ownership Structure and Service Provision. Pattern Change over Time: Evidence from Medicare. Home Health Care Market Ownership Structure and Service Provision Pattern Change over Time: Evidence from Medicare Home Health Care Hyunjee Kim December 7, 2012 Abstract While many economic studies have addressed the static

More information

Mandatory Medi-Cal Managed Care: Effects on Healthcare Access and Utilization

Mandatory Medi-Cal Managed Care: Effects on Healthcare Access and Utilization Mandatory Medi-Cal Managed Care: Effects on Healthcare Access and Utilization Yashna Nandan April 30, 2017 Abstract Medicaid managed care is often presented as the panacea for spiraling healthcare costs.

More information

PHCA Webinar January 30, Latsha Davis & McKenna, P.C. Kimber L. Latsha, Esq.

PHCA Webinar January 30, Latsha Davis & McKenna, P.C. Kimber L. Latsha, Esq. PHCA Webinar January 30, 2014 Latsha Davis & McKenna, P.C. Kimber L. Latsha, Esq. 1 2 Intended to: Encourage the development of ACOs in Medicare Promotes accountability for a patient population and coordinates

More information